Skip to main content

Notes taken from SI Cohen's book "World Development and Economic System"

                                   


                                    Notes taken from S.I. Cohen's Book

              "World Development and Economic System"



Chapter 1 INTRODUCTION

 

·                     The objective of this book is to present an integrative theory of economic systems, demonstrate its applicability time wise and worldwide, and make use of its implications for policy and designs. In assessing studies of economic systems, it is necessary to distinguish between those which focus on the indepth study of (one) economic system, ISEC, and those that undertake a comparative study of (several) economic systems (CSES).

 

·                     ISEC have commonly distinguished between three broad economic systems that are generally labelled as the traditional system, the (centrally) planned system and the (decentralized) market system.

 

The first major contributions on the working of the traditional system came from anthropologists. It suffices to mention Malinowski (1922), being the first to describe the institution of reciprocity as a guiding rule for exchange of goods and services, conceived as gifts among kinship and tribesmen in Polynesia. Their conclusion is that in traditional settings, exchange is determined in the context of institutions of reciprocity and of sharing that are typical of closely knit personal relationships based on loyalty to shared kinship, community and belief. Another wave of studies was concerned with the informal economy in rural and urban areas, especially in the developing world, among the first to coin the term was Lewis (1955). The informal economy was traditional in its sociological relations and production technology and was politically non-participative.

 

Studies of the planned system were short lived, starting around the initiation of Soviet Plans in the 1920s, and ending with the collapse of the communist regime towards the end of the century.

 

Studies of the functioning of the market system and the history of economic thought have been tied to each other from the very start. The elements of the market system that were outlined by Adam Smith (demand and supply determining prices in competitive markets, combined with utility maximization and profit maximization by consumers and producers) required refinements and extensions involving great economists including Pareto, Walras, Marshal, Samuelson, Arrow, Debreu and others before these elements were rigorously integrated and formalized in a static general equilibrium theory of interlinked markets, some three centuries later. The growth dynamics of the market system is due to Schumpeter (1943), which he saw as being led by innovations and entrepreneurs, but is retarded by increased power of corporatism and greater monopoly. This is a form of market failure that urged Schumpeter to argue for a shift from a capitalist distribution of wealth and decision-making powers to a socialist distribution. In due course, other economists pointed to other market failures and the need for market and non-market solutions to mend these failures, i.e. Stigler (1971) on capture practices; Coase (1960) on internalizing externalities, Stiglitz (2008) on reducing financial instability and so on.  As the market system evolves over time, it sets in motion other effects and norms that can be experienced as negative or positive, depending on the value judgment of the evaluator. The most prominent negatively conceived effects are human alienation and conspicuous consumption. Marx (1867) was moved by the negative effects: the market system with its focus on private property, business capitalism and strict division of labour degraded and dehumanized labor, and estranged him from his true nature. The theme of estrangement and alienation was revisited and elaborated further by Polanyi (1944): The market system with capitalism as its driving force gave birth to a new economy that is disembodied from its social environment. By commoditizing not only goods but also labour in terms of exchangeable money, the market capitalist system dismantles a whole lot of protective institutions for the common people. Veblen (1899) focused on the pecuniary culture and conspicuous consumption that are seen as an outgrowth of the market system economy. Conspicuous consumption served as a public display of the spender of his economic power and is as such a waste. Levy-Gerboa (1979) elaborated on conspicuous consumption by linking the joint collaboration of producing firms and admired leaders of consumption styles in the introduction and communicating of new consumption styles and products in the market. Friedrich Hayek and Milton Friedman are convinced that the market system fosters freedom and democracy. All the above negatively and positively conceived side effects of the market system have some truth and are recognizable by the objective observer.

 

·                     We can move now from the ISES to the CSES, whose contributions have been remarkably lower. In the first part of the past century, there were some outstanding theoretical contributions that compared the market system with the planned system, such as by Barone (1909) and with the traditional system such as by Polanyi (1944). In the past century, CSES was influenced by the ideological divide and the cold war between a western and an eastern camp. s. It is not surprising, therefore, that as the communist regime faltered by late 1980s, CSES came to face an identification crisis. Instead, many CSES repeated their custom of the past century of elaborating typologies of double and triple term labels and sticking them to the countries studied, in what is named varieties of capitalism. For instance, Hall and Soskice (2001) started humbly by classifying the industrialized countries into a liberal market system (i.e. USA, UK) and coordinated market system (i.e. Germany, Japan). Amable (2003) extended the classification of the market system to five types or models: market-based model (USA, UK), social-democratic model (Scandinavia), Continental European model (Germany, France, Netherlands, Belgium), Mediterranean model (Greece, Italy, Portugal, Spain), Asian model (Japan, Korea). Lane and Myant (2007) added four more categories to fit transition countries in the capitalist picture. Bohle and Greskovis (2007) brought in even more complexity by adding another four–isms: neoliberalism, embedded neoliberalism, neocorporatism and transnational capitalism. Formally speaking, CSES should be backed by an integrative analytical framework that explains how and why different economic systems emerge.

 

·                     We identify three subsystems: households, firm settings and state settings (that is, governmental settings). We model the economic transformations within the three subsystems, as well as inter-transactions, inter-communications and inter-mobility of agents between the subsystems. We postulate that over long time periods of agent interactions, three prototypes dominant systemic behaviours would emerge in different environments and histories, leading to three distinguishable prototype economic systems: (1) a household intensive system where agent interaction is centred around social sharing household settings, (2) a firm intensive system where profit maximizing firm settings dominate agent preferences, institutional conducts and system performances, and (3) a state intensive system where rent acquiring governmental settings dominate agent preferences, institutional conducts and system performances.

 


 

Chapter 2 An Integrative Theory of Economic Systems

 

·         In this chapter, we outline a theory on the formation, evolution and differentiation of economic systems. Our framework emphasises the location and interaction of agents in distinct behavioural subsystems and constituent settings, as the clue for understanding how agents, and the economic system they form, become aligned with particular behavioural setting, take over the typical behavioural type that associates with that behavioural setting, and spread it to other settings via various channels. We display the mechanisms involved that lead to one subsystem dominating other subsystems and drive prototypes of economic systems that associate with each of these settings.

 

Components of the economic system

 

·         Behavioural settings relevant for economic analysis are those that generate for their participants added value from the economic transformation of some production and/or exchange activity. Agents inhabiting a behavioural setting engage thus in a value-added transformation of goods and services. Actions of agents are subjected to physical technological boundaries and guided by institutional rules and information schemes. Setting - household, firm and state settings. These three types of settings will be denoted by h, f and s.

 

·         A specific subsystem consists of a vast number of behavioural settings of the same specific type. The subsystems corresponding with the household, firm and state setting will be denoted by H, F and S, respectively. Each subsystem has its own institutional rules and information schemes for guiding actions of the agents present in that subsystem. Agent behaviour and institutional conduct in a subsystem and its constituent settings are driven by an intrinsic goal function typical of the subsystem. Household settings h form together the household subsystem H, firm settings f form together the firm subsystem F and state settings s form together the state subsystem S. One represents delivery of agents of one subsystem to another subsystems and related agent interactions; another represents delivery of transformed goods and related monetary transactions between the subsystems. The long arrowed lines linking the subsystems stand for inter-deliveries of agents and their related communications, and for transformed goods and related monetary transactions.

 

·         In the developing world taken as a whole, about 60% of the labour force are in rural household-based settings and in urban informal settings where self-employment and family workers in tiny undertakings is the primary employment mode. The remaining 40% is about evenly divided with 20% in the modern private sector employment (firm settings) and 20% in the modern public sector employment (state settings).

 

·          In the developed world, there is only a few percentage points of the labour force, say 5%, that pursues economic activities that can be described as non-commercially household based, or as belonging to the social economy (i.e. voluntary, cooperative and non-profit). Roughly about 70% of employment is in the private sector (firm settings), while about 25% is in the public sector (state settings).


 


·         starting from the micro layer of settings, then to the meso layer of subsystems and last to the macro level of the whole system.

 

SETTINGS (h,f,s)

·        First, what are the major ‘types’ of settings that engage in economically relevant transformation processes; what are the intrinsic goals of these types of settings and their forms of transformation?

 

·         In any society, there are tens and tens of distinct types of behavioural settings, with each type having its own goal with which participating agents associate and identify. Our concern is limited to settings that are economically active. Agents inhabiting such a behavioural setting engage in a value-added transformation of goods and services, with given physical technological transformation capacities, making use of information flows and subjected to institutional rules. We have distinguished between three main settings of relevance for the study of economic systems: household settings, firm settings and state settings.  The intrinsic goal in household settings can be described as affinity sharing, the goal of firm settings is generally stated as profit maximization, and the goal of state settings is best described as securement of polity rent, in short, rent politicization. The coordination mechanism in traditional household settings is typically sociologic in character; in firm settings, coordination is economic and in state settings, coordination is political.

The distinct behavioural motives of the three types of settings, we call them also intrinsic goals, can be expressed formally as is done in Eqs. (2.1–2.3). In the household setting, the agents lump together their benefits and costs in an effort to make total benefits exceed total costs. In Eq. (2.1), Vh stands for the value added in the household setting, while rewards R and efforts E of agents i and i ‘ are lumped together and somehow shared among all i. The institutional rules that regulate conduct in the household organization are so designed that agents would thrive to distribute these benefits and costs between i and i ‘ in ways that contribute to a maximum value added or at least a positive result for the whole setting.

 Vh ≡ Ri + Ri’ − Ei − Ei’ ≥ 0.                             (2.1)

 In the firm setting, each agent would like to realize the highest economic returns to one self, which implies aiming at realizing the highest return to the firm as a whole, in competition with other firms. Institutions for regulating conduct within and between firms are designed towards that end. In Eq. (2.2), Vi stands for the value added in the firm when agents i and i’  maximize their relative returns, defined as benefits less costs per unit of capital invested; the latter can be approximated by taking multiples of the total costs, or to simplify things we set the total costs as the denominator.

Vf ≡ Σ(Ri − Ei)/ΣEi ≥ ρ.                                  (2.2)

To model the state setting, we introduce in the variables R, E, V , the subscript ps to denote the situation before engagement of the state, and subscript s to denote the situation after engagement of the state. We also employ k to represent agents with state authority. Equation (2.3) shows a lower value added in the pre-state situation compared to the situation with state engagement, that is Vps < Vs. This is due to a reorganized transformation with intervention of state agents k that results in ΣRi > ΣRpsi and/or ΣEi + ΣEik < ΣEpsi. Part of ΣEi is a privately incurred cost and the other part is the collectively invested expenditure that allows for the higher value added transformation.

 Vps ≡ ΣRpsi − ΣEpsi ≤ 0,     Vs ≡ ΣRi − ΣEi − ΣEik ≥ 0.                                 (2.3)

 Institutional rules in state settings give the governing agent, k, the exclusive authority to acquire a polity rent from all agents for the polity services rendered, denoted by Eik . Furthermore, institutional rules in state settings tend to be moulded in manners that require prolonged dependency of agents, i, on agents with state authority, k, and collection of polity rent in the future if transformation is to be realized and maintained in future transactions.

·        Second, what are the means of transformation in the (economically relevant behavioural) setting, and how do they jointly drive the transformation process?

 

-          In any of the three types of settings, four means (or factors of production) are combined in the transformation process, and applied to realize the specific goals. The four means are (a) interacting agents, (b) institutional rules, (c) a given physical–technological transformation capacity and (d) information schemes.  Interacting agents play a central role: The transformation is operated by a population of interacting agents unified by the same goal setting. Some agents turn up to be more suited to lead and take initial decisions and actions, we called them leading agents; while others wait and see, evaluate and follow or simply trust or act blindly in a herd behavioural manner. All these are called follower agents in one sense or the other. The transformation process is set into motion by a complex of information flows communicated by agents to each other.

 

·        Third, how do these means change over time? In particular, how do agents participate in settings?

-          But there is also a more insightful answer to the question, which elaborates on the dynamics between settings. These dynamics occur through reshuffling of agents across settings and through the redistribution of transformation volumes across settings. Major shifts in agent membership of alternative settings are put into motion by the mobility of agents between settings, preceded by a search by agents for settings in which the individual agent can combine his/her endowments and preferences most satisfactorily. As a result, the distribution of persons and transformations among settings is adjusted and new configurations are reached, which in turn has important implications for adaptations and changes in the institutional rules, transformation capacity and information flows of each and every setting.

 

- The distributed rewards of competing settings are crucial for an evaluation that participants regularly do, and which guides them in their decision to continue in the setting or move to another setting.

[i] Stays in the setting, functions in full conformity with roles and rules (i.e. loyalty).

 [ii] Stays but protests. Attempts to enact changes in functioning of organisation (i.e. protest). [iii] Stays but acts passively and practices moral hazard (i.e. undermine).

 [iv] Exits, searches and enters eventually another organization (i.e. exit).

 Hirschman (1970) was among the first to emphasize the notions of loyalty, voice, exit and entry. Leader and follower agents move from one setting to another. the mobility continues up to the point where the propensity to move satiates in the sense that the marginal utility for an individual of shifting a unit of effort between settings is equal to the marginal cost of the shift.

 

·        Fourth, what is the role of the (external) environment in conditioning the settings?

-          Different external environments generate typical coordination structures that coincide and fit with typical behavioural settings. This (h) external environment promotes sharing behaviour and solidarity structures coinciding with and taking place in household settings. The f setting promotes profit maximization and commercial exchange structures taking place in firms and markets. External environments typical of state settings s are characterized by highly skewed human endowments, esteem and rank among differentiated population groups

 

THE SUBSYSTEMS (H,F,S)

·         Proceeding from the level of settings to the level of subsystems involves objectifying the settings, that is to say depersonalizing them and turn them into entities that relate to each other as such, and supplementing these entities by additional institutions for safeguarding the sustainability and expansion of the subsystem. there is a widening of the scope of economic activities at the subsystem level when compared to the setting level.

·         A subsystem is much more than the sum of its constituent settings, i.e. constituent entities. All entities in a subsystem have the common interest of sustaining the common goal of their subsystem. To that end, the entities within a subsystem join together and erect institutions at the subsystem level that promote their typical transformation processes, and secure their sustainability.  The deepening of the motivational goal of the setting towards that of a collective motivational goal for the subsystem as a whole is the case in point why the whole is greater than the sum of the parts.

·         How do acts of free riders affect the collective motivational goal of the subsystem?

The non-competitive practices of free-riding firms raise their profits but undercut the profit potential for the subsystem of all firms; and to illustrate, the free riding reduces achievement level of profit maximization for complying firms.  

·         Each subsystem erects institutions aiming at strengthening its sustainability and growth. The degree of success that the subsystem achieves in holding its members together and avoiding free riding is conditioned by how the external environment develops.

 

INFLUENCES AND DOMINANCE OF ONE SUBSYSTEM OVER SUBSYSTEMS

 

1.     Interactive influence

 

·         The interactive influence focuses on agents and is determined by the degrees of participation and activity of the agents. The same agents can be members of more than one setting simultaneously.

·         The squares, triangles and circles (in above fig.) refer to the three organizational settings, each with its own members; the arrowed lines linking them are engagement lines which indicate transformation and mutual exchanges taking place among agents in or between the organizations, as well as communicated behaviours. Each engagement line can be interpreted as consisting of a large number of bits of exchanged transformations and communicated traits. Such an engagement line can be denoted by Gibi’b’. As these bits are not uniform in intensity in terms of time, effort or effects, they can be normalized making use of some scale of engagement intensity, which can be denoted by N, and expressed in terms of time, effort or effect. The engagements weighted by intensities can be expressed by Σib(Gibi’b’.Nibi’b’). This term can be eventually divided by the sum of all engagements weighted by intensity in the whole economy to give a relative measure of the strength and dominance of the engagement lines.

·          The engagement lines express agent mobility between alternative settings. A better performing subsystem attracts more agents from less performing subsystems, and tends to become dominant. Over time, the behavioural motive of the dominant subsystem becomes the norm for whole system. Thus, one subsystem is very likely to evolve into, and be identifiable with the whole system.

·         Some six mechanisms, that may include overlapping, can be singled out as determining the formation of the common, its spread and dominance.

 (1) Sharing of the same external environment and past history fosters convergence towards a common behavioural type. Furthermore, accumulated agent interactions and economic activity over long periods of time enhance agent uniformity.

 (2) Intensive and extensive interactions and communications of agents participating in several settings are prone to extend the prevalence of the advantaged behavioural type that associates with dominant setting or subsystem.

 (3) Agents observe the transformation outcomes in alternative settings, and move to the advantaged setting or copy its behaviour thus resulting in the prospect that the typical behaviour of the advantaged setting becoming prevalent.

 (4) Network externalities enforce convergence towards the advantaged behavioural type.

(5) The deep-rooted social-psychological inclination of agents, or for that matter all individuals, toward consistency in their relationships and cognitions, ends up in adopting a positive attitude towards the preferential behaviour of the dominant counterpart. This is the premise in balance theory of Heider (1958), which holds that individuals constantly seek to achieve balance where social relationships enter into conflict, by either changing their sentiments or attitudes toward dominant persons or situations, or by subjectively diminishing the importance of the conflict.

(6) There is a wide range of labelled mechanisms that have been approached from different corners in the literature on convergence and concentration of social systems around specific behavioural types. These labelled mechanisms overlap with our six broad channels. These mechanisms include imitation, convention, focal points, information cascades, reciprocal behaviour, group learning, Markov chain inversions, melting pot and power of dominant shares, among others.

 

·         We propose to formulate a Dominance Index (DI) to express the interactive influence of subsystem B on other subsystems, denoted by DI B. The index has two arguments: relative share of agents in B and relative share of transformations in B. See Eq. (2.4).

 DIB = (ω1AB + ω2CB) ≥ ν     (2.4)

 In this equation, there are two share parameters that affect prevalence. AB is the share of agents in subsystem B. CB is the share of commodities most suitably transformed in subsystem B, in all commodities. Personal commodities are most suitably transformed in firm settings. Collective needs are most suitably transformed in state settings. The probability that a behavioural type characteristic of subsystem B prevails over all other Bi occurs when DI for B exceeds a high value of ν. In this equation, ω1 and ω2 are weights applying to these two shares, whereby ω1 + ω2 = 1. Equation (2.4) proposes that the greater the shares of those agents and commodities associated with a particular setting, the greater is the probability that the behavioural type underlying this setting prevails over other behavioural types.

 

We introduce ν which is a proportion that represents a critical mass. Once the practice of a particular behavioural type reaches this critical mass, this behavioural type can be expected to benefit from network externalities and to extend its maintenance to practically the whole population. There are different views concerning the likely value of the critical mass. A value of 3/4th (0.8) is among the most quoted in the literature on a critical mass, cf. Simon (1993). Once this threshold is reached, the dominance of the subsystem concerned and its characteristic behavioural type, this characteristic behaviour can be expected to gain momentum in view of network externalities. Network externalities push the dominance of one subsystem over other further.

 

2.     Regulative influence

 

·         By regulative influence, we mean a situation in which a behavioural setting b happens to stand higher in relation to b’ in the hierarchy of settings; allowing b to set behavioural rules typical of b that other settings b’ should abide with. In this way, the behavioural type of b overrides b’ , allowing the further spread of behavioural norms of b at the cost of those of b’ . The origin of the regulative influence lies in the ability of the higher settings to impose binding rules of conduct on the lower settings. n.. The interactive influence represents the results of horizontal integration. Regulative influence is a vertical relationship. In the horizontal channel, agents in setting b are many and have a high intensity of interaction. These agents participate as well in setting b and interact with agents in b , and thus transfer their behavioural type to b , so that in time, agents in setting b’ take over the behavioural type characteristic of setting b. In the vertical channel setting, b stand higher up than b in a relational hierarchy. Binding rules of conduct are imposed by setting b that setting b should observe, resulting in behaviours and outcomes of b that are consistent with those of b. The dominant power of the firm subsystem is the result of the past growth of interactive influence and is less the result of a regulative influence of the firm subsystem on other subsystems.

 

DOMINANT SUBSYSTEMS AND RELATED PROTOTYPE SYSTEMS: HIS, FIS, SIS

 

·         It is unlikely in the real world that complete convergence occurs, in the sense of 100% of all agents converging towards the same motivational behaviour of the dominant subsystem, we speak of prototypes of economic systems rather than absolute systems.

 The first prototype, and the oldest, is the economic system that centres on households and in which agent behaviour and institutional rules in the whole social system have adapted to household behavioural traits. This can be called the household intensive system, HIS.

The second prototype is the economic system where agent behaviour and institutional rules in the whole social system adopt a firm-like behavioural type, i.e. maximization of economic returns. The firm intensive system, FIS, has many copies in the real world; the best example is the US.

 The third prototype is the economic system where agent behaviour and institutional rules have adapted to a statelike behavioural type that is characterized by rent acquisition and political advantages. In the real world, Soviet Russia was the typical example of a country that operated along the state intensive system, SIS.

 

·         We postulated that the intrinsic goal functions of the minor subsystems are modified so as to accommodate to the goal function of the dominant subsystem. But the latter is not totally immune from some influence due to the minor subsystems. The indirect planning methods by the state in France that is otherwise an FIS-centred country is one example. Another example is the polder consensus model in the Netherlands which has its origin in the 16th–17th century. Some aspects of the sharing economy in Japan go back to tribal sharing centuries ago. The Chinese kinship-business model which esteems competition and deals between kinship-related entrepreneurs is traceable in the current conduct of the F and S subsystems in modern China. Many transition countries traces of rent politicization and rent seeking from past communist regimes.

 

EXPLORING PATHS OF DOMINANCE FROM A COMMON STARTING SITUATION

·         It is helpful to postulate the development of the three subsystems as an outgrowth from some common origin, which is by definition, the customary household settings. Now that there are firm-centred and state-centred economic systems, then how did they proceed from the customary households? There are two main approaches in answering these questions. One approach would start by emphasizing the differentiated effects of differentiated external environments, which is very basic, and revert to external events and internal dynamics in a historical-institutional timeline fashion and trace their impact on the developments of the subsystems/system in different countries. An alternative is an analytical modelling approach that would examine how changes in external forces affect the comparative advantages (i.e. the prospects) of the subsystems; such external factors would include technological change, demographic growth, higher welfare and the changing patterns of human needs with respect to private and public goods.

 

·         The starting point is conveniently the situation where household settings are already there. Which settings followed: firm settings or state settings? Hicks (1969) is among the many economists who contend that tribal chief, feudal landlord, army and state settings historically preceded firm and market settings. Social anthropologists, like Firth (1967), maintain that economic organization and the transformation and exchange of products within and between neighbouring primitive societies came first and preceded political organization.

 

·         The formation and development of a subsystem is subject to weakening and strengthening effects that associate with events and traits occurring in the external environment. Weakening of subsystem B is defined in the sense of agents and transformations leaving B and going to B’ , thus leading to a decline in the significance of subsystem B and a rise in the significance of B’ . Another form of weakening is when agents shirk from the goal function, succeed unsanctioned in violating the institutional rules and realize personal gains at the cost of a greater loss for the conforming agents; thus resulting in a net loss for the subsystem. For agents to leave or shirk, some inducing changes in the external environment (challenges, opportunities) must have occurred.

 

·         The ages of geographical discovery and colonial conquest in the 14th–17th centuries strengthened both subsystems in Europe, though more so for S than F. The industrial revolution in the 18th–19th centuries brought technological advances which enhanced major diversifications in demanded private goods, a huge jump in personal needs of the newly settling migrating populations and a significant push for the firm subsystem; this period also saw the subjection of state governance to constitutional law which, in terms of dominance, was equivalent to a downgrade of the state subsystem. Frustrations with an unfair and insecure social order and nationalist aspirations in the 20th century encouraged calls for authoritarian rules and led to a dominant state in various parts of the world; in some cases, the duration was temporary as in the ex-Soviet Union, in other cases, it is still going on. The financial crises in the western world and the rise of China and India as leading economies in the 21st century are fresh and the directions of their long-term effects for the F and S subsystems.

·         Which subsystem came first: F or S? We present here a modelling framework of long-range systemic development that allow for both scenarios. The framework is basically microeconomic, and is based on several premises.

 (1) Agents inhabiting household settings, and interacting with each other in a communal environment, experience specific needs, or can be attended to uncovered needs, and they are ready to embrace these needs. Agents are also innovative and capable of finding solutions and creating new transformation settings that satisfy these needs.

(2) The needs of an agent can be personal or collective.  Personal needs of one agent can be directly satisfied by the innovative and responsive transformation offered by another agent; opening ways for exchange and firm settings. Collective needs are indivisible and their satisfaction would require a joint effort of agents and a third-party intervention to coordinate the task at a higher level; which opens ways for public goods, delegated authority and state settings.

 (3) In communities where personal needs happen to have an overweight, the firm setting will emerge and prosper. In communities with an overweight of collective needs, the state setting will emerge and prosper.

 (4) The model assumes tentatively that the external environment is kept constant, and allows for subsequent refinements.

 

EXPLORING ABSENCE OF DOMINANCE: THE MULTI-POLES SYSTEM (MPS)

 

·         In this multi-poles environment, the need to streamline the vast heterogeneity of agents has enhanced the significance of what can be called persuasion settings, an adapted notion from Murphy and Shleifer (2004), where divergent groups with different interests are parts of a network of trustees who aim at proposing common agenda and coordinating actions to meet the collective needs of the divergent groups.  Figure  sketches main contours of MPS.



·          Persuasion settings take place in the context of large family firms with state participation, joint business-state ventures, township and village enterprises, urban and rural cooperatives, as well as in the widely publicized influential events that recur in party congresses, judiciary courts, populous rallies, government decrees and intellectual and media disclosures. While persuasion settings do not constitute economic transformation settings in the conventional sense, they do perform value-added transformations in the sense of arranging negotiated deals and producing trading services in ways that are formally not different from what traders do in the market.

·         Our consideration of persuasion settings is short of treating them as a subsystem.

 

 MORE DYNAMICS: INTERACTIONS BETWEEN WORLD DEVELOPMENT AND ECONOMIC SYSTEMS

·        We have chosen as title for this volume “World Development and Economic Systems”, but it could have also been “Economic Systems and World Development”. There is a continuous interaction between (a) world development and (b) economic systems. Changes in (a) can change (b), and changes in (b) do not go unnoticed in (a).

 

THE EVALUATION FRAMEWORK FOR ECONOMIC SYSTEMS

·        In welfare economics, it is usual to distinguish between welfare criteria, such as economic efficiency and social equity and performance indicators, such as economic growth rate, income distribution, poverty incidence, inflation rate, etc.

·        The objective measure of economic efficiency is conventionally taken to be Pareto optimality which states that any change that makes at least one individual better off and no one worse off is an improvement in social welfare. Rephrasing, a situation in which it is impossible to make anyone better off without making someone worse off is said to be Pareto-optimal or Pareto-efficient. It should be emphasized that the Pareto criterion is a value judgment as it might not be shared by everybody.

·        The attainment of maximum economic efficiency is obstructed by the following four complications in the real world. (1) Production indivisibilities allow increasing returns to scale which give cost advantages to giant producers able to monopolize and limit competition. (2) Imperfect governance caused by imperfect information heightens uncertainty, and reduces activity, noting that imperfect information associates with adverse selection and moral hazard. (3) Presence of externality effects violates the independence of utility functions of consumers from each other and the independence of production functions. (4) Public goods cannot be marketed but they have to be produced and financed.

·        But this maximum is not unique, for it presupposes a given distribution of income. Here comes the equity criterion. Besides, whatever degree of Pareto-efficiency attained, this is subjectively related to the underlying distribution of endowments (income and wealth).


 

Chapter 3 EMPIRICAL VALIDATIONS

 

·         This chapter falls in the next section that proposes the positioning of country (groups) along the prototypes of household intensive system (HIS), firm intensive system (FIS) and state intensive system (SIS). There are tens of international agencies that have set up their own databanks resulting in a multitude of overlapping country groupings. We shall focus on and make use of the databank of the World Bank (WB) as our main source, as it is the one most used and most flexible to modify. The classified groupings may have been meaningful and useful when it was initiated in the past, but may have become absolute and confusing over time. We have adjusted the WB databank to the above-mentioned modifications. In summary, the modifications relate primarily to the introduction of two additional country groupings: RRTC which is closest to a contemporary SIS, and CAC which is a dynamic development region that saw its birth some two decades ago.

 


One additional elaboration can be mentioned. In pursuing the analysis of SIS, and how relating economies restructured and performed during their transition towards mixed economies, we made an additional temporary distinction between the Baltic, Central and East European countries (BCEE),1 which later went up in the EU et al., and the XSIR,2 which later substantiated the CAC development region.












·         We can now go ahead with the positioning of the distinguished country groups along the axis of the three prototypes of economic systems. The positioning shows US to be most close to the exemplary FIS, while Japan and West European countries, also positioned as FIS, yet showing differing inclinations towards HIS and SIS, respectively. West European countries lie on the right of US and reflect a state control inclined economy that is characteristic of SIS. Japan lies on the left of US and reflects a household sharing-inclined economy that is characteristic of HIS



·         We have in mind, four levels of system interaction which we came across in Chapter 2, and which can be briefly described as

(1) identity of the attitudinal behaviour of agents with the subsystem or system which they inhabit,

(2) institutional conduct is specific to the subsystem or system considered,

 (3) economic performance is specific for the subsystem or system considered and

 (4) the relative influence of subsystems is measurable via the dominance index, and together with other deductive indicators, they can be indicative of convergence tendencies of the total system towards the dominant subsystem.

 

AGENT ATTITUDES

·        One line of validation of the theory is to check on the degree of conformity between the motivations and attitudes of agents and the contended motivation of the subsystem, or system, to which these agents are affiliated. An important data source on agent attitudes is the World Value Surveys (WVS). The survey is a compilation of national surveys on values and norms on a wide variety of topics. It started in 1981 and was carried out in 1981– 1984, 1990–1993, 1995–1997 and 1999–2004.

·        The WVS data also show a higher prominence of family settings and family related attitudes in the FIS industrial countries than in the SIS transition countries; suggesting that firm settings have been more accommodative to familial institutions than state settings. Especially in the context of the ex communist rule in the transition countries, the state appears to have undermined household settings at a greater pace. This is also apparent in the low ratings reported for China and Vietnam.

 

INSTITUTIONAL CONDUCT

·        There is the well-known index of firm competition — also called ‘Index of Economic Freedom’, which is based on 10 indicator groups: (a) business, (b) trade, (c) fiscal, (d) government control, (e) monetary, (f) investment, (g) financial, (h) property rights (i) corruption and (j) labour mobility. Higher values of the index for a country represent a greater strength of its firm subsystem.

·        Another indicator that reflects on the influence of the state subsystem in FIS countries is the share of state revenue in the GDP.

OUTCOME PERFORMANCE

·        It was mentioned earlier that a household intensive economic system is less capable than firm-centred or state-centred economic systems in producing larger valued transformations.

·        (a) in its economically optimal form, competing firms in the firm-centred economy would maximize their profits to the point where inefficient profits would be eliminated by more entry and exit of firms; and if this is realized, the maximum economic welfare obtains; and

 (b) the state in a state-centred economy can achieve the same maximum economic welfare, if it succeeds in obtaining the right information flows and coordinating them; and if it is able to calculate its exploitation margin right and implement it, that is to say, it will not impose a too high inefficient margin that could reduce the size of the cake and the ultimate margin as well. Both conditions may not be tenable.

·        Both groups [ SIS and FIS countries]  experienced high growth [ average annual growth of the GDP, and the GDP per capita]  from 1950 to 1970. The growth of SIS countries started declining in the mid-1970s and reached a standstill in late 1980s. What is the source of the decline? To get more insight in the problem, distinguish between extensive growth that is identical with growth of factors of production such as labour and capital inputs (which need not be specific to the system), and intensive growth that is identical with growth in total factor productivity, i.e. more output per unit of input (which is usually specific to the system). It is generally acknowledged that during the early stages of economic development, economic growth tends to be of the extensive growth type, as output expansion is achieved largely from mobilising and using more factor inputs. At higher stages of economic development, intensive growth dominates as factor productivity increases significantly through better use of the factors of production, higher technology, more efficiency, etc. It is generally recognized that the pace of factor productivity is greatly determined by the structure and conduct of the economic system concerned.

·        The usefulness of these distinctions is readily seen from Eq. (3.1). Take v, for growth rate of output, to consist of the two components: growth in factor use and growth in factor productivity. The first component is the weighted sum of the growth rates of inputs of labour l and capital k, the respective weights should reflect their respective marginal returns as represented, under market equilibrium conditions, by each input’s share in the national income, thus rl and rk. The second component is the growth in factor productivity,

 y. v = (rll + rkk) + y.                                      (3.1)

 

 By inserting the value of the growth of output v and the growth of weighted input (rll + rkk) and deducting, the growth in factor productivity y is obtained as residual.

 

·        Rather than becoming more intensive, the growth of the communist regimes continued to be more extensive. For a modern economy, the opposite pattern of intensive growth should have happened. The very low past performance with regard to factor productivity has manifested itself in what was previously mentioned as failing outcomes of the communist system, such as persistent shortages, waste due to misallocations, backward technology, low quality of goods and services and retarded advancement of well-being.

·        The other outcome that we focus on is the distribution of the value added on the agents. Because of the sharing norms in HIS, income distribution here is likely to be most equitable among the three systems. In FIS, distribution of the value added is likely to show greater concentrations of returns for agents who are more suited as profit maximizers, and given their smaller number among all agents, this implies a skewer distribution in firm settings than in state settings. In SIS, although the average remuneration for agent k is higher than the average level of net benefits left over for agents i, it is in the interest of the governing agent k to satisfy the governed agent i in terms of material needs and observed remuneration, which would generally result in a less skew distribution in state settings compared to firm settings. Moving from a SIS system to a FIS system will necessarily result in a skewer distribution of primary income.

·        A readily available indicator for both FIS and SIS countries that comes a long way towards fulfilling the relevance conditions is the ratio of per capita income for persons in the 75th percentile to the per capita income for persons in the 25th percentile.






 

Chapter 4     EVOLUTION AND EVALUATION OF THE

FIRM INTENSIVE SYSTEM  IN FIS-CENTRED COUNTRIES

 

·        We have described the Anglo American countries, European Union (EU), Japan, Korea and a few other countries as firm intensive system (FIS)-centred countries. US as closest to the pure FIS, while Europe and Japan are placed on the sidelines that link with state intensive system (SIS) and household intensive system (HIS), respectively. As all FIS countries interact with each other intensively, they can be viewed as a world system that holds together in maintaining its FIS-centred character.

·        The configuration in Figure  is consistent with descriptive studies of capitalist economies. These studies generally agree on a distinction between three configurations for industrialized economies: the liberal-oriented, the regulation-oriented capitalist and the reconciliation-oriented systems.



·        In the liberal-oriented capitalism, coordination is run along commercial logic and profit maximization by firms, moderated competition monitoring and limited public goods provisions and income transfers. This profile is typical of the Anglo-American industrialized countries, in particular UK, Canada, Australia and led by United States.

 

The regulation-oriented capitalism supports regulated competition, moderate factor mobility, moderated income differences and a larger state budget. Firms tend to shift part of their response in the correction of market failures towards the state. Although the resulting state interventions can be interpreted as serving the social interest, they may at times serve the benefit of special interests, and if they are too many, they can restrict the free operation of commercial exchanges. This profile is typical of most continental European countries. The orientation can be related to the state subsystem that used to be more influential up to the 18th century in continental Europe.

 

The reconciliation-oriented capitalism is one based on frequent negotiations between firms, workers, community leaders and public authorities at various levels of decision making with the object of reaching consensus agreements among these groups on restrictive and promotional measures that correct for market failures and bolster group welfare. The reconciliation approach in Japan often contains elements of fair sharing of benefits and costs among the involved parties, which is a common principle in household settings, and can be seen to be a surviving influence from the otherwise practically extinguished tribal-customary household subsystem.

 

HISTORICAL DEVELOPMENTS

 

·        In Europe, the marathon began in a period of fragmentation and vacuum, around 900 or 1000 AD. Once the race was started, the leading subsystem at the time (that of traditional household settings) experienced a continuous loss of agents and transformation to the benefit of rising subsystems. A spectacular gainer in the 11th–13th centuries was the theocratic subsystem (church and related settings), but this dwindled in later centuries. The feudal–lordship–manorial subsystem (an overlapping combination of feudal, lordship and manorial settings) was another spectacular gainer in the 10th–13th centuries, but was destined to disappear completely five centuries later. It took manor law, urban communes and the central monarch another five centuries of reformist and constitutional revolutions to evolve and fuse into the democratically elected state subsystem that is characteristic of western countries today. Small in size but rising in terms of agents and transformations were merchants and craftsmen. Although the trading, crafting and cottage industry settings expanded with growing markets for goods, labour and finance, it was only six centuries later, with the industrial revolution (IR), that these settings developed into firm settings; and it took the firm subsystem two more centuries to evolve to their present dominant position in western countries.





The period of 1000 to 1400

·         Uncertainty, fragmentation and defeat in the 6th to 10th century were at maximum levels, the dominant traditional household subsystem already started to crack down, and newly emerging subsystems started showing their mussels. The 11th to 14th centuries provided historically the right times for newly emerging settings to consolidate themselves into emerging subsystems and establish institutions that assure their sustainability. Foremost among the newly emerging subsystems

 

1.       The Papal revolution and crusade wars : It was only in the 11th century with the commencement of the Papal Revolution that the Christian Church organized itself as a coherent and unified theocratic subsystem, and was able to exercise substantial influential powers on other subsystems. Dictatus papae, initiated by Pope Gregory VII, circa 1050–1080, has been named by legal historians as the Papal Manifesto. Legal historians, Berman (1983), trace the origin of the Western legal tradition back to the Papal revolution. The crusade wars were a major world development of the time. The traditional household subsystem was further weakened.

 

2.       The feudal–lordship–manorial subsystem: The feudal subsystem was strengthened by manorial laws. In the feudal subsystem in Europe, the monarch loaned land to vassals (i.e. lords, often belonging to nobilities) in exchange for loyalty and protection. At a lower order, the lords loaned land to their own vassals (i.e. peasants), and so forth. There were thus different levels of ‘vassalage’. The lord granted lands to peasant households in exchange for military service and working the land, whilst the vassals were ensured work, homes and protection. The feudal subsystem gained momentum with the crusade wars. It was a main supplier of soldiers and food. But the growth of the feudal subsystem and manors began cracking in later centuries as social mobility among peasants increased and the bondage with land decreased.

 

3.       Urban communes: Councils and parliaments were an integral part of the organization of the commune, which showed quite a high degree of participation in the making of decisions cf. Hyde (1973).

 

4.       Trade guilds: The crusades required production and maintenance of transportation means on land and sea, costumes, metal weapons and related tools, which meant an enhanced role for traders, transporters and craftsmen and an emphasis on acquiring skills and training apprentices. Merchant and occupational guilds came into being in these years. As trade and travelling increased, road piracy increased. This prompted lords to employ armed guards for protecting traders, in exchange for fees; which set in motion the introduction of standardized currencies that propelled the exchange economy further. The trade and craft guilds formed the seeds of the firm subsystem, F, which became dominant in later centuries.

 

 

The period of 1400 to 1700

 

·         We focus on four major developments that occurred in this period. Two additional major developments took place later in the period.

 

1.       The Renaissance: After reaching their climax in the 12th century, the grip of the Papal revolution and the supremacy of the supernatural began to diminish in the 13th century. Reliance upon absolute faith weakened. The Renaissance, or re-birth, began in Florence, Italy, a few decades before 1400, and spread later to the rest of Europe. The two outstanding revolutionary changes in this age were those of the protestant reformation and of the parliamentary democracy, which have been labelled by historians as the German revolution and the English revolution (in contrast to the Papal revolution which was based in Italy). Humanists like Niccol`o Machiavelli, and Thomas More emphasized the virtues of intellectual freedom and individual expression.

 

2.       The Reformist Revolutions: Martin Luther started the German revolution in 1517 by challenging ecclesiastical authority in the most radical terms. In 1529, ruling princes and city representatives, in support of Luther, protested the imperial decree, and civil war broke out. It is from this protest that the name Protestant is derived.

 

 The English revolution was led by Reformist Puritans, who in 1640 formed a majority in the parliament that was seldom convened, they opposed the absolute reign of the monarch. The Puritans were English followers of the French reformer, John Calvin, who established a protestant community in Geneva which denied the authority of the Roman church. “A civil war broke out in 1640 between the Puritans (mostly reformist trading and craft guilds in towns and countryside) and supporters of the monarchy (conservative churchmen and landlords). The Puritans seized power, formed a commonwealth government, trialled and executed King Charles I for treason and abuse of power in 1649. As it often happened in history the immediate governments after a revolution had a short life, this was also the case in England. Ten years later, the Puritan rule collapsed in 1658. The king’s son, Charles II, was restored as monarch. When the next monarch, James II, resumed abuse of power, he was forced to abdicate and a new dynasty was installed in 1688. Henceforth, the governing authority was the parliament and not the king.

 

3.       The world discoveries : Although the roots of the discovery age go back to the Vikings, the crusaders, and the eyeopeners of the Renaissance, the immediate need for explorations came from the war successes of the Ottoman Empire in the Middle East and their ability to obstruct overland trade routes from European to the spice-growing Asian countries. In reaction to these barriers, governments and traders in Portugal and Spain started exploring new ocean routes to Asia. Political power and economic trade were major motivations. While succeeding in opening a southern trade route to Asia by sailing around Africa into the Indian Ocean; Spain and Portugal stumbled across the Americas. Soon after, the Dutch, British and French followed. Italian citizens (C. Columbus) and ports (Genoa, Venice) played central roles in explorations and trade.

 

4.       The colonial conquest:  After the discovery of the Americas With limited native populations in the colonies, the colonial governments and traders looked for other workforce sources: slaves. Triangular trade involved three stages: Carry first goods such as cloth, spirit, tobacco, beads, metal goods and guns from Europe to Africa. The goods were sold to Afro-Arab slave traders in exchange for more slaves. The guns were used to help expand empires and subjugate slaves. The second stage was an inhumane shipping of the slaves to the Americas. The third stage was the return to Europe with the produce from the slave-labour plantations: cotton, sugar, tobacco, molasses and rum. To increase their income from taxes in the triangular trade, European monarchs encouraged the formation of joint stock companies. Stocks (or shares) were sold to investors who shared the expense and risk of expensive ocean trading voyages. If a ship went down, no single investor lost everything, but if a voyage was successful, all stockholders shared in the profits. Most voyages succeeded, and many investors made good money. Since the joint stock companies of the colonial era were chartered by governments, they were a form of state-sponsored firm ownership. This is a bright example of how the state subsystem has strongly supported the firm subsystem.

 

5.       The rise of nation states: . Generally speaking, the state is a coordinated polity system with geopolitical boundaries, while the nation implies a unified population along cultural, religious, linguistic and other related dimensions, territorially bounded. The term nation state implies that the two combine in one, and thus reinforce each other. The rise of nation states in 1400–1700 boosted significantly the authority and strength of the state subsystem in Europe. portant roles in the development of the nation state in different countries. The nation state gathered strength in the age of world discoveries and colonial conquests. Mercantilism rationalized that the nation state should apply national political norms in ruling over national economic interests, and that the objectives of the nation as identified by the central monarch were superior to those of traders and craftsmen. The goal of national policy was thus to strengthen the national economy and weaken foreign adversaries by monopolizing crafts and markets, restricting imports, accumulating surpluses in the balance of trade and expanding overseas colonies.

 

6.       The rise of business metropolis:  A crucial development in the economic history of Europe was the major shift of economic power from the Mediterranean Sea to the North Sea, which went along with the creation of multi-purpose business metropolis in the latter. A business metropolis is a large city or urban area which is a significant economic, political and cultural centre for a country or region, and an important hub for regional or international connections, commerce and communications. By building the business metropolis, the merchant class minimized the cost of exchanges (i.e. search, negotiation, enforcement and financing costs). Enforcement costs of contracts were facilitated by public notaries attached to the markets and sanctioned by government. Another major breakthrough was the development of a financial market which was driven for a part by fiscal borrowing needs of foreign governments, France and Spain among others. The liquid business leaders were ready to lend. Short-term and long-term depositing and lending to many sorts of customers grew significantly, facilitated by establishment of banks and the legal right of transferring and endorsing obligatory letters of payment to third parties.

The period of 1700 to 1900

 

1.       Enlightenment and the Constitutional Revolutions: The Enlightenment era (1700–1850) is held to be the source of critical ideas, such as democracy, rights, liberty and reason as primary values of society. Montesquieu’s Spirit of the Laws had expounded the theory of separation of powers; by placing the functions of legislation, executing, and judging in three wholly separate compartments, with legislation supreme over the other two. Rousseau taught that law should rectify inequalities that arise from natural differences among people. In his Discourse on Inequality, he proposed that inheritances ought to be reduced by taxes, and that those who owned no land receive some. As is generally known, the American Revolution (1775–1783) started with Jefferson’s Declaration of Independence (which contained ideas from the Political Enlightenment), establishing the independence of 13 North American colonies from Great Britain and creating the republic of the United States of America. At around the same time, the events of the French Revolution rolled.

 

2.       Economic thought and the IR:  Technically speaking, the IR began in Great Britain around 1760 and within a few decades spread to Western Europe and the United States. A first phase ending in 1840 converted hand production methods into mechanical ones, introduced new chemical manufacturing and iron production processes, and developed machine tools. As regards energy, wood was replaced by coal, steam power introduced, and water power improved. A second phase, between 1840 and 1870, saw increasing adoption of steam-powered boats, ships, railways and factories, and the large-scale production and use of machine tools.

 

 Even though the prerequisites were present, yet the IR once started, it overturned the whole socio-economic and polity system upside down. The IR fuelled the creation of the profit maximizing firm settings as we know them today. The firm is hence a factory or a workshop that the risk-bearing owner/manager/entrepreneur sets up, and it is populated by hired regular employees who engage in the mechanical transformation of inputs into outputs (intermediate and final products). The outputs, scheduled for sale at stipulated prices by the owner, can end up in other prices once subjected to market forces of demand by all consumers and market forces of supply by all producers. These modes of production, distribution, pricing and clearance were made real by the IR. Classical economists, i.e. Adam Smith (1776), succeeded in specifying and knitting these different modes into a consistent static economic system in which consumers and producers pursuing utility maximization and profit maximization, respectively, and left to their own, would equalize their respective demand and supply at variable prices in perfectly operating markets. s. Classical economists highlighted the circular flow and the growth dynamics of a profit maximizing firm-driven economic system. Because profit rates tend to diminish as more competing firms enter into production, competing firms seek to innovate and widen the scope of production towards more goods with higher profit margins.

 

The conclusion to draw at this point is that economic thought laid down the foundations for promoting the processes of the IR and the dominance of the firm subsystem on other subsystems. By the end of the 18th century, feudal manors and urban communes were fused in the state subsystem, trade and craft guilds became part of the firm subsystem; and theocratic settings seized to have significance in the economic system. Before ending this section, it is important to emphasize one major difference between the classical economists (1700–1850) and neoclassical economists (1850 and later), which we consider as crucial for our analytical framework. While the attention of the classical economists was foremost on markets, the neoclassical economists brought the firm explicitly in the picture.

 

 

The period of the 20th century and recent years

 

·         The state subsystem in the western world, after going through the German, English, American and French constitutional revolutions, can be said to have reached its polity trajectory and satiation point already by 1820 or some two decades later.  In the 20th century and later years, we single out the following major events and comment on their [firm]  systemic impacts. The major events include two world wars, two great financial collapses and several breakthroughs in political and economic western integration.

 

1.       WWI (1914–1918): The enormous cost of the war undermined the financial stability of all of the countries involved and their state subsystems had to bear a burden of debt for many years to come. These financial losses, combined with the battlefield deaths and physical destruction, severely weakened the western front European powers, and pushed US to become a world political power and the world’s largest economy. On the east front and one year after the war, the Russian Revolution replaced the czarist regime by communist rule.

 

2.       WWII (1939–1945): The contra parties were the same as in WWI, except that this time Germany’s allies included Italy and Japan. The outcome in terms of gainers and losers was also the same as in WWI. The terms of peace were totally different, however. Instead of losers paying war indemnities, the losers and the west European gainers entered in a period of post-war construction financed for a large part by the US, while the Soviet Union (with allied and/or subjugated east European countries) continued along its communist track.

 

3.        Great Depression (1929– 1942): Began in the US and spread to most FIS countries. The “Roaring” 1920s in US was a prosperous time, allowed excessive enrichment of some, inflated expectations of many, fuelled the demand for financial credit, leading to a bull market and ending in a bursting speculative bubble in October 1929. The financial meltdown was followed by the longest recession in modern times. By early 1932, banks failed massively, wiping out the savings of millions of Americans. Unemployment reached 25% at a time when unemployment benefits did not exist. Mortgages on many homes and farms were foreclosed. Furthermore, a severe drought spread across the Great Plains in 1930 and lasted for a decade. Recovery started with the election of President Roosevelt (his New Deal introduced programs to reduce unemployment, assist firms, regulate banking and the Stock Market, and help the needy). With the outbreak of World War II in 1939, the US began spending on armament and other war expenses materials, which further strengthened a period of industrial growth. The event of the Great Depression allowed the Federal Government to expand its domain to meeting collective needs in social welfare, and regulate the financial market. In the early 1930s, regulations were introduced to restrict stock purchase on margin and coordinate risk taking in banking; in the hopes that another severe crash could never happen again. But history replayed itself some 75 years later.

 

4.       The financial crises (2007–2009): Started in US in 2007, took the proportions of a financial meltdown in late 2008, and spread globally to other linked financial markets economies, bringing them into economic recession in 2008 and 2009. The main cause is an overexpansion of lending activities that started from 2001 much beyond the ability of borrowers to meet obligations to pay back (the unregulated shadow market in US reached a worth of US$50 to 60 trillion). The overexpansion was facilitated by the use of very risky, dubious, undisclosed and complex newly introduced financial products and credit default swap insurance contracts that defy monitoring and regulation. In attempts to restore financial confidence and recover the economies from recession, state interventions in FIS countries ranged from temporary nationalization of financial institutions to capital injections, and bailouts of troubled investment banks; next to massive stimulus spending in the economy to combat the recession.

 

5.       Integration of the FIS into a consolidated firm intensive world subsystem: The establishment of the North Atlantic Treaty Organization (NATO), the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) and the EU were major steps in the integration. Extension and harmonization of trade liberalization policies under the auspices of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) set into motion business forces that are eager to introduce more competition and secure mutual gains for the FIS as well as for other countries.

 

6.       Globalization:  Globalization entered the world scene in the mid 1988 as the GATT initiatives gained momentum with various rounds of mutual tariff cuts, reduction of non-tariff barriers, passing norms for government purchases from firms, export and farm subsidies, and dumping practices. Replacement of GATT by the World Trade Organization (WTO) with additional tasks of liberalizing trade in services, settling trade disputes and facilitating investment between member countries promoted globalization further. Freer trade, together with higher mobility of capital, labour, knowledge, shared media and interactive communications worldwide gave a big push to globalizing processes with significant impacts on business and state organizations.

 

 A summary illustration of the changed relative powers of main subsystems in FIS countries

 

1.       Early centuries:                                  H, R

2.       9th–10th Century:                            H, T, M, R

3.       11th–14th Century:                          H, M, T, F, R, S

4.       End of the 17th Century:                 H, F, R, S, M, T

5.       End of the 19th Century:                 F, H, S, R, T

6.       End of the 20th Century:                 F, S

 

H : Traditional Household settings  R: Royal settings, T: Theocratic settings, M:  Feudal manorial settings, R: Royal settings,   F: Trade-->Firm settings,   S:  Commune-->State settings

CHALLENGES AND RESPONSES

The free market economy model, market failures and policy responses

·        Welfare economics derived four efficiency conditions that need to be satisfied for achieving economic efficiency in the sense of Pareto-optimality. The efficiency conditions are the absence of production indivisibilities, imperfect governance, externality effects and collective needs. If because of various barriers the efficiency conditions are not fulfilled in a market economy, one can speak of corresponding market failures.

·        If all firms and agents behave competitively there will be free entry and exit, there will be no barriers whatsoever to exchange, all firms and agents will be price-takers at the same price for the same commodity, and a simultaneous equilibrium will be obtained by all agents in all markets — hence the term general equilibrium. In this pure model, market prices carry significant information. Each commodity price would reflect the buyer’s marginal valuation relative to other commodities. Moreover, the price of a commodity will be equal to its marginal costs. This guarantees the lowest possible costs that society is ready to sacrifice for a commodity. The First Theorem of Welfare Economics is a proof of the above account: If the marginal rules hold, then the resulting competitive market equilibrium is Pareto-optimal. Guided by equilibrium prices the self interested decision of the economic agents lead to a social optimum in the Paretian sense. This is another way of viewing Adam Smith’s notion of the invisible hand mechanism. The performance of the perfect market economy in the hands of firms depends on how firms respond to four problem areas. There are technical barriers and behavioural distortions that hinder fulfilment of these conditions. The solutions lie respectively in strengthening competition, reforming governance, internalizing externalities and the balanced provision of public goods.

·        There is the Second Theorem of Welfare Economics that prescribes that any Pareto optimal position is an equilibrium for some initial distribution of endowments. There is a dilemma here since any initial distribution of endowments or income is arbitrary, implying there is no one Pareto optimal position. The economist’s solution to this dilemma is to assume that a democratically elected parliament or an appointed council of wise elders men would review the income distribution situation at the end of the year and resets this ex-post, giving due consideration to the perception of a desirable initial distribution and unintended differential outcomes during the year. Transfers are then affected in consistency with the resetting. If the resetting is well done and duly implemented, then the outcomes of the FIS can be described to be in harmony with the desired equity perspectives, even though this happens with a lag in time. Deviations of the actual from the desired distribution of income can be thus seen as a market failure, in addition to the four other market failures mentioned earlier. Traditionally, welfare economics has given less attention to the topic of how to deal with wealth distribution. More recently, there is renewed interest in this problem area, Piketty (2014).

 

Table: A sketch of market failures in FIS countries.



 

Production indivisibilities

·        In the real world, technological indivisibilities in some vital industries persist and translate in increasing returns to scale (or decreasing costs) making it likely that the industry will end up with one single firm. Even if a natural monopoly does not arise, the presence of indivisibilities gives an advantage to incumbent firms, which could restrict entry, promote non-competitive practices, fix a high price and receive a monopoly profit. 11 infrastructural industries that are characterized by high indivisibilities  are post, telecommunications, electricity, gas and water, oil, coal, railways, airlines, motors, steel and ship building. The discussion below examines the challenges and responses regarding

 

1.        Natural monopoly:  appears when economies of scale are important. With a natural monopoly, average costs are declining, and marginal costs are below average costs. Hence, if prices were set equal to marginal cost, as in the case of perfect competition, it would be less than average costs and the firm would be losing money. If the community wanted a natural monopoly to produce at the point where marginal cost equals price, it would have to somehow support the industry to offset these losses up to the point of nationalizing the industry and fully regulating it. The opposite alternative is that the industry is privately owned and run but that the production and price of the product are regulated in some degrees. These two alternatives, nationalization versus regulation, are found in various combinations in FIS countries.

 

Considering the nationalization alternative, the presence of large capital costs and economies of scale turn some industries into natural monopolies such as electricity and railways. There are several problems that accompany nationalized industries. It is hard to ensure that the industry does minimize costs. This is a problem of information access and mechanism design between agent (management) and principal (ministry). The managers of nationalized industries often lack adequate incentives to cut costs and modernize vigorously; particularly given the fact that government is frequently willing to subsidize the industry when it loses money. In the regulation alternative, the dominant firm persuades other firms, and the state, to accept this dominant firm as the sole owner of the natural monopoly, while entrusting the government with the role of ensuring that price is kept at the lowest possible level, commensurate with the monopolist’s obtaining an adequate return on its investment. Prospects for the regulatory system in FIS countries are constrained by two levelled objections. The first objection is that regulations often result in inefficient practices. The second objection relates to regulatory capture, which implies that the regulator gradually comes to identify with the interests of the company it regulates.

 

The US approach towards controlling infrastructural industries with large indivisibilities and potential monopolies avoided nationalization, favoured entrusting ownership of these industries to the private sector, and preferred to regulate the business practices of these industries. In contrast, European countries were more for nationalization of infrastructural activities. The national share degree is defined as the share of the state in the ownership of an industry and calculated as a simple average over the 11 industries.

 

2.       Imperfect competition: As most industries operate under less than full capacity, they are able to set a market price that is higher than marginal costs. The advantage will not be as permanent as in the case of the monopolist but may be just sufficient to serve as a barrier for entry. Seen from the monopolist point of view, monopolistic practices (reducing supply and increasing price) lead to more profits. Seen from the viewpoint of competing firms, the monopolistic practices limit the gains and perspectives of the competing firms. Viewed by the community as a whole, the monopolistic practices result in (a) restricted output with higher prices, (b) efficiency loss as the monopolist lacks incentives to economize and falls in managerial slack, (c) wasteful costs incurred to limit competitive entry in case the monopolist intensifies rent seeking actions and (d) retarded growth and lesser equity in the economy.

 

3.       The trade-off between perfect competition and technological advance: entrepreneurs facing strong competition may simply lack time for long-term planning and for undertaking more elaborate projects of R&D. Besides, in a situation of heavy competitive pressure, profits are usually so low that little room is left for the internal financing of R&D activities. These considerations led to adopting national policies that are receptive to a restricted competition that promotes rapid growth of cost efficiency in the long term, on the condition that the restricted competition does not lead to a monopoly power that eliminates competition. The opposite scenario was recognized as well. Firms orient their investment, R&D efforts towards making profits, which are highest with monopoly power. This consideration led FIS countries to adopt national policies for fostering competition-oriented technological growth.

 

Technology policy in FIS countries can be stylized in two approaches: the single company approach and the perspective synergy approach. In the first approach, individual firms are seen as technology leaders and the state would focus on the innovating firm and attempt to find the right balance between firm behaviour that capitalizes on innovations and sufficient incentives to motivate development and application of innovations. In the econd approach, the focus is less on firms and more on industries: the presence of market imperfections is accepted but more emphasis is put on the future perspective of alternative technologies at the industry level. In this approach, an evolutionary framework is followed which seeks to find the right balance between the knowledge cycle and information synergies, and suitable forms of cooperation between industries and the state.

 

Imperfect information and imperfect governance

 

·         Imperfect information is classified by two types of sources, depending on whether the source is technical or behavioural.

 

1.       Incomplete information: In essence, the demand for and the price of the product that the producing firm face are random. As a result, profit is also random, and strictly speaking, is difficult to set at a maximum. As a substitute for profit maximization, optimal decision-making theory perceives the objective function of the firm to consist of the firm’s attitude towards risk, and the firm’s perception of the likelihood of various outcomes. The greater the uncertainty, the greater is the departure from risk-neutral attitudes. Furthermore, the more incomplete the information on expected outcomes, the greater is the randomness of profits and the less is the validity of the profit maximization objective.

 

2.       Asymmetric information: Akerlof (1970) was among the first to draw attention to behavioural mischief, which is synonymous with imperfect governance. His example was that in the market for sale of used automobiles, the seller will in general have more information about the properties of the cars sold than the buyers. Initially, buyers might think that the odds are 50–50 that a car they buy will be high quality. When making a purchase, buyers would therefore view all cars as being of “medium” quality. (Of course, after buying the car, they will learn its true quality.) As a result, fewer high-quality cars and more low-quality cars will be sold. This shifting continues until only low quality cars are sold. At that point, the market price would be too low to bring forth any high-quality cars for sale, so consumers correctly assume that any car they buy will be low quality. Because of adverse selection, low-quality goods drive high-quality goods out of the market.

 

Externality effects

 

·         In general terms, an externality can be said to exist when a decision variable on buying or selling of one producer or consumer cannot be excluded from entering directly into the utility or production function of some other producer or consumer. This can be expressed by the following expression Ui = Ui (xi1,...,xin, yi ) where utility U of agent i depends on excludable goods x ranging from 1 to n, produced and/or consumed by agent i, as well as some non-excludable activity y carried by agent j. The externality problem relates to economic interdependencies, which are not incorporated, or so as to say not effectively internalized in the exchange economy. Two additional comments need to be made before dealing with examples. First, an externality was defined as a side-effect, either good or bad, that results whenever a person or firm making a decision does not consider social costs or social benefits of the particular decision, and, as a consequence, directly affects the utility or profits of other consumers or producers. Second, externalities can be positive or negative ( development of the railway system and seaports / Air or water pollution ) .

 

·         Industrial and trade policy is a suitable example for illustrating responses to positive externalities. Commonly, industrial policy would refer to government actions which aim at growth and change either via (a) a general shift of productivity and/or enhanced activity across the board or via (b) a reallocation of means in the economy in such a way that current and new activities with better perspectives (high rates of social benefits to social costs) get higher weights at the cost of other activities which are less attractive (low rates of social benefits to social costs). The first channel is often called the neutral approach; the second channel is the targeted approach. The approach adopted by the US government can be described as a ‘missionoriented’ approach. Industrial policy in Western Europe is mixed. British industrial policy is based on a liberal philosophy, that industrial performance is best left to the private sector, assisted only at the margin by state activity. Germany has applied both approaches to industrial policy. Japan has mostly promoted a sectoral approach. Trade policy is best seen in the context of the WTO which plays a central role in the promotion of greater competition between firms in member countries and in enhancing international trade via encouraging neutral industrial policies and trade liberalization.

 

·         In FIS countries, a variety of firm-market solutions and state measures have emerged to internalize polluting effects. Firm responses include creating internal markets via forcing unitization, and defining and enforcing property rights. Unitization is the creation of single ownership and control of resources whose uses might conflict to create an externality. Unitization does pose one problem, however. Creating a single owner for the different activities may create a firm with market power. Then solving one problem — an externality — creates another problem — a monopoly

 

Collective needs

·         If certain goods are not profitable, the firms will fail to produce them. If nevertheless a community collectively considers such goods as necessary, they become public goods and the state is called upon to be the organizer/funder/ contractor to the hired producers of the public goods.

·          In the extreme, the first feature of a public good is that it cannot be supplied to one consumer without simultaneously being supplied to others. When the good is provided for one agent, it will bring external benefits to many other agents. This feature is known as non-excludability

·         Also in the extreme, the second feature of the public good is that once the good has been supplied to a single consumer, there is no additional cost in supplying it to others. The supply of benefits generated by the good is in no way depleted no matter how many people use it. This feature is known as non-rivalry, implying that the cost of supplying an extra user with the good is zero.

Endowments distribution: Income and wealth

·         Welfare economics postulates that for a given endowment distribution (income wealth), the market mechanism will result in an economically efficient outcome whereby costs will be minimized while satisfaction will be maximized.

·         The problem arises when more agents feel that the existing distribution is unfair, to them or to others; and when this feeling is transformed in actions that would affect the economically efficient outcome of that moment negatively. To prevent a market failure, or better said a system failure, major leaders in the private and state sectors respond jointly with actions that assure ‘fair’ outcomes for all agents. Conceptually, there are two approaches economists use in treating the question of what is ‘fair’: a positive and a normative.

·         Transfer payments consist of unemployment benefits, pensions, and so on. It is important to notice that these payments do not represent a claim on the absolute resources of society (in contrast with exhaustive expenditures). Rather, transfer payments are flows of income from individuals in society to other individuals in society passing the government sector as an intermediary.

 

 

THE POLITY SYSTEM IN FIS COUNTRIES

·        The relationship between the state and firms in a capitalist economy has been a regular subject of modern political and economic thinking.

 Schumpeter contributed to the view that the capitalist system would be dominated by monopolist firms which would collaborate with a powerful state. The partnership would strengthen both forces to the detriment of other players.

 There is an opposing view by Hayek that monopoly firms are transient and the capitalist economy will manifest a competitive and continuous entry and exit of firms, which by implication will exclude coalitions between firms and the state.

There is a third position that lies somewhat in between. Stigler coined the word capture to denote the tendency of monopolistic firms to use the regulatory state to bolster the firm’s own market power. Stigler allows also for newcomer firms to lobby for their entry and use the state accordingly. In all three cases, the firms are dominant actors and the state rulers are side-line beneficiaries.

·        There were periods in recent history in which large firms collaborated with a powerful state along the lines of Schumpeter. But contemporary FIS-centred countries correspond more with the viewpoints of Hayek and Stigler, than Schumpeter. Regulatory captures and state lobbying by incumbents and newcomer firms occur in Europe, US, Japan, but these captures are transient in a FIS economic system where regular entry and exit of firms wipe out such captures. While Stigler holds in the short run, Hayek holds more for the long run.

·        The intrinsic motive in political behaviour, which we termed rent politicization, is replaced by profit maximization in the firm intensive economy. In FIS countries, it is therefore plausible to consider profit maximization as the underlying common behavioural pattern of most actors, thus in firms and state, and households. Correspondingly, the political process in such a system can be described as a commercialized exchange process. This comes to saying that the S subsystem operates just like the F subsystem in the FIS-centred country.

·        The political market can be described basically as consisting of buyers and sellers who undertake mutually beneficial exchanges of political compromises and material benefits within a world of varying uncertainties. The voters are the buyers: they demand security, regulations, services and redistributions from the political parties and governing leaders. In exchange, they pay taxes.

 

 The governing party is comparable to an incumbent company that supplies goods; the opposition party is an aspiring company. The roles of the political party and its political leaders are comparable to those of the company shareholders and the company board of directors. Political leaders in government, as ministers or deputy ministers, or in opposition strive to maximize votes gained, and once elected, most political leaders may opt for short-run personal gains, acquire rewards and satisfactions while in office, or use the office to maximize future influence outside politics.

 

 State bureaucrats executing plans of ministers, can be compared to business managers, are responsible for overseeing and implementing regulations and provision of public goods like defence, roads, health, education, etc. The appointed ministers and state bureaucracies run the government and are the final suppliers of political solutions. The relationship between the minister and the bureaucrat has much to do with principal-agent relationships and asymmetric information. Bureaucracies are experts on their field of research whereas their political superiors, the ministers, only have the general view of what is going on in the departments. Because it is too costly for any individual minister to monitor bureaucracies, the latter have an opportunity to influence the quantity and efficiency of public sector output in biased ways.

 

Although public sector employees are not active agents in the political process, they indirectly play a central role in shaping the polity and economy. Another set of actors in the political market place consists of interest groups like individual firms or associations of firms, employer organizations, trade unions, regional areas and so on. In reaching their objectives, interest groups mobilize bureaucrats and politicians to circumvent regulations, and raise public provisions to the advantage of the pressure group concerned.

Political media is the next political actor, it engages in information search and dissemination. Their role is close to that of advertising agencies that highlight the merits and demerits of political suppliers, their leaders, associates and operations.

·        In the FIS-centred country, the economic and political markets share various similarities. Just like a normal market for economic exchanges, the political market can be described to face similar limitations in the way of a perfect functioning. Perfect competition, in the context of political market, exists if parties would compete and thereby eliminate abnormal ‘profits’ that might arise due to discretionary behaviour on the supply side. However, in reality, a lot of these conditions are not satisfied, just like in normal markets. Turning to polity mechanisms, the urge for political parties to win as many votes as they can, drives them to adopt policies favoured by the median voter. Thus, the majority-voting equilibrium is the policy preferred by the median voter.

 

PRIVATE AND PUBLIC SHARES IN FIS COUNTRIES

·        On the whole and for many decades, public spending has been increasing at a higher rate than private spending in FIS countries.

·        Second, what does the economic literature say on the growing share of the public sector? Adolf Wagner (1835–1917) was among the first to specify the relationship between the public sector and GNP. Wagner’s law, as it became to be known, states that an increasing share of public expenditure in GNP accompanies the development of an industrial economy. Wagner observed and predicted that public spending grows at a higher rate than GDP.

·        Firms and households alike have an increasing demand for public goods and this requires more public spending and an extended state sector; besides, there are inevitable exogenous forces such as periods of wars and emergencies that raise the need for collective action and a greater share of public spending, and the community as a whole recognizes and endorses these needs and their implications.  State and politically motivated agents strive to enlarge their spheres of influence and public spending. These agents fall under politicians, bureaucrats ( Maximization of ministerial budgets, Underestimation of specific costs, Overestimation of general costs) , interest groups and public employees.

·        The works of Musgrave (1969) and Rostow (1971) have looked at the time pattern of public expenditure in the development process of countries fitting most in the FIS. Following them, three phases in the development process are commonly distinguished: the start-up phase, the growth phase and the maturity phase.

·        Third, how to interpret the effects of the rising public share on the dominance of the F subsystem on the S subsystem? A substantial part of the increase in the public share is in the form of transfers and subsidies which end up with the public. The numbers of public employment have barely changed in FIS countries, and in some countries, there were cutbacks so as to meet budget deficit ceilings. Public revenue has been short of public spending. While interactive influence is not affected by the rise of public share, regulative influence of the state subsystem is likely to have increased with a higher public share. However, the state relies on the business community for a large part in financing the budget deficit, which gives business a mutual control leverage on the state.

·        Fourth, an intriguing issue is the negative relationship between government size and economic growth. The two variables of public share and GDP growth show opposite trends since the 1960s, as is demonstrated in Table.

 

Baumol’s model

 

Baumol (1967) formulates the problem formally in the following model. Take X1 as the output of the non-progressive sector, and X2 as the output of the progressive sector. The production functions of each sector are then as follows:

 X1t = a1L1t                                                                                                         (4.1)

 X2t = (a2ert) L2t,                                                          (4.2)

 

 with L1 and L2 being the labour force in the non-progressive and the progressive sector respectively, t is the time index and a1 and a2 are constants. The production in the progressive sector is assumed to grow at an exponential rate of r. Equations (4.1) and (4.2) are used to derive the ratio of government output to total output, as shown in Eq. (4.3).

 

 X1t/(X1t + X2t) = a1L1t/(a1L1t + ( a2ert )L2t) .                     (4.3)

 

An implication is that if the ratio of public sector output to private sector output is to remain constant, then it must be that labour is transferred from the private to the public sector. This is indeed observed in reality. It is assumed that wage rates are equal between both sectors and that they follow increases in productivity in the private sector. w0 is a constant, and wt is the wage in period t.

 

wt = w0ert.                                                                        (4.4)

 

 From the equations above, unit costs are derived for the public and private sectors in the next two equations.

 

 C1t = [(w0ert )L1t ] / [a1L1t]  = w0ert/a1                                           (4.5)

 C2t = [(w0ert) L2t ] / [(a2ert)L2t]  = w0/a2.                                        (4.6)

 

 From Eqs. (4.5) and (4.6), it follows that unit costs in the public sector will rise steadily, while private sector costs remain constant. Together with Eq. (4.3) another conclusion of the model is that public exhaustive expenditures will rise faster than private sector expenditure on inputs. The growth potential of the economy is only partially realized.

 


 

Chapter 5                      EVOLUTION AND EVALUATION OF THE

                          STATE INTENSIVE SYSTEM IN SIS-ORIENTED COUNTRIES

 

·         The state intensive system (SIS) orientation in these countries had in common the sharing of a communist regime for about 70 years (since 1919 in case of Russia) to for about 40 years (in case of allied countries) with significant effects on agent behaviour and the institutional makeup. We have made a distinction in Chapter 3 between a hard core SIS-oriented Russia and Russian tied countries (RRTC), and the country groups of Baltic, Central and East Europe (BCEE) and the ex-Soviet Islamic Republics (XSIR), which manifest SIS tendencies though in lesser degrees. The three groups pursued different transitional paths from 1990 onwards.

 





DEVELOPMENT

·        The timeline offers brief descriptions of systemic changes in the communist regime in the upper half, and of the political engagement of the SU in world development in the lower half. While the upper half focuses on the economic system, the lower half focuses on world development.

·        A civil war followed during 1918–1920 between the left and liberal wings of the communist party, ending in absolute authority for the left wing. Once the inner left-liberal crises of the communist party was settled, the first major economic decision taken by the communist regime was initiation of the New Economic Policy (NEP), in 1921, which was meant to partially integrate the market economy in the command economy. However, NEP was reversed in 1924, and the SU started adopting a constitution that reinforced public ownership of means of production and their management by the state. This centralist line gained in strength as Stalin succeeded Lenin. Adoption of the first FiveYear Plan was in 1928, with the state setting goals and priorities for the whole economy. This signified the end of the New Economic Policy, NEP. As collectivization of agriculture proceeded, property of millions of peasant households was confiscated, and numerous relatively prosperous peasants lost their life.

 

 The development of the communist regime as an economic system, from the early 1920s and up to its end in the late 1990s, is best described by Kornai (1967) as a confrontation between a control and the real. It was the task of Lenin, and his followers starting with Stalin, then Khrushchev, Brezhnev, etc., and ending with Gorbachev to defend the declared communist ideology and soviet promises, safeguard state capitalism and develop control procedures for running the economy in ways which will hopefully approach these promises. The real world diverged from the control world and this was the central barrier in the fulfilment of the soviet promises.

 




 

During 1985–1989, Gorbachev, the last to lead the SU, declared policies of openness (glasnost), restructuring (perestroika), and acceptance of a freely operating private sector. The initiatives were obstructed by the Chernobyl nuclear explosion, and by nationalist outbreaks in Afghanistan, and in other parts of the SU. As the pace of reforms by Gorbachev was criticized by Yeltsin, his challenger, regime instability heightened. As an economic-political breakdown appeared eminent, the Communist Party was forced to vote for ending the one-party rule. At the other end, on election of Yeltsin as president of the Russian Soviet Federative Socialist Republic by the latter’s parliament, Yeltsin dismembered himself from the Soviet Communist Party, banned the Soviet Communist Party in Russia and seized its assets; thus formalizing the end of the communist regime in Russia, and factually the whole SU, which is seen by some historians as basically a construction inspired by Russian national interests.

 

Recovery returned with transitional reforms. RRTC continued their attachment to the SIS orientation, the BCEE group integrated with the EU and the XSIL group integrated with the Central Asian and Caspian development region.

 

·         During this span of 50 years, the SU exploded its first atomic device; recognized the Communist government in China, supported North Korea, instituted the Warsaw Treaty Organization (which gave ground for Soviet intervention in Eastern Europe to maintain their satellite status), launched the first manned orbital flight and placed missiles in Cuba which led to a war-likely crises between US and SU in 1962. Settlement of the Cuban crises by withdrawal of the missiles opened a period of East–West d´etente which lasted between 1963 and 1978. During this period, the SU joined the US and Britain in 1963 in signing a treaty banning atmospheric nuclear tests; and SU and US set up a ‘hot line’. Clashes across the border between Soviet and Chinese troops in 1969 brought SU closer to US. In 1972, SU and US signed the SALT-1 arms control agreement, heralding the start of d´etente.

 

·          The period of d´etente was formally ended in 1979 when Soviet troops invaded Afghanistan. The East–West cold war was once again on the running, with conflict areas mainly sought in the developing world. But the SU was at a disadvantage in this phase of the cold war as nationalist outbreaks erupted in the European allies and in Afghanistan, forcing Russia to draw its troops from Afghanistan under heavy casualties. Other setbacks such as the death or removal of five top communist leaders in the SU in 5 years, the political duels between the last two leaders Gorbachev and Yeltsin, and the instability and weakening of the communist regime and its predictable breakdown, encouraged nationalist independence in the Baltic republics Armenia, Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan and Georgia. With the end of the communist regime in 1990, and with the recognition by Russia’s president Yeltsin of the independence of the Baltic republics, Ukraine choose for independence, followed by other republics; the Congress of People’s Deputies of the SU had no other option than to vote for the dissolution of the SU; thus, practically speaking, reducing the territory of Russia to what Russia used to be before Soviet communism.

 

Development of the communist regime: Contradictions between the control and real worlds

 

·         The communist regime of the SU contained four control rules, which generally speaking apply to an all-political state intensive economic system, SIS:

 

(i)                  The state’s ideology: The state has a communist ideology that offers the best promising prospects for the people. In the real world, Russian national interests and ideals were given higher priority than the communist ideology in the organization, implementation and content of pursued policies.

 

(ii)                The state’s party:  The communist ideology and realization of its promises are contracted to the state’s one and only communist party. In the SU, the party cadres was known as nomenklatura. The top of the nomenklatura is the politburo, whose decisions become the law of the land. Members of the politburo do not have tenure. To be removed from the politburo is a very great loss, hence the eagerness of persons in the top to form protective alliances among themselves. In practical terms, the economic system no matter how it will turn out to be, it was embedded in a predetermined polity. This meant the subjection of the economic order to the political order. By simultaneously politicizing all information and decisions, the party eliminated possible corrective feedback mechanisms. Politics superseded economics.

 

 

(iii)               State ownership of property:  State is the sole owner of property. Collective farms and gardening plots for the collective farmers were tolerated but were not transferable. The only fully accepted private property was that of consumption goods which people pay for from the earnings or transfers they received from state enterprises or state authorities, respectively. In the real world, the law of state ownership was reducible to merely a facade hiding the true owner.

 

(iv)               The central planning system:  State is the sole coordinator and driver of the economy via a directive system of resource allocations. With nationalization of the means of production in the SU by the ruling Politburo, a system of central planning and administrative command was put in place in 1928. We shall explore this system in terms of procedure, methods, practical operation and planning reforms.

 

·          The economic plan used to be formulated along the following procedures. General directives on economic development were provided by the politburo, and converted into control figures by the central planning department, Gosplan. Tentative production targets for major commodities were then sent to the ministries for further specification, and from there down to the level of individual enterprises falling under the supervision of each ministry. The enterprises were supposed to send back comments and information on limitations and prospective. Ministries adjust and send ministerial plans to Gosplan. It was here that the final matching between inputs and outputs for a large number of commodities, varying at times between a few hundred to a few thousand took place via the use of material balancing methods, resulting in final production targets. These were disaggregated further and disseminated to the ministries and through them to the concerned individual enterprises. Consequently, there were ministerial plans focussing on aggregates, and enterprise plans that took up details. The plan for each enterprise contained detailed directives on input provisions, operations, outputs and deliveries — from whom and to whom — for the forthcoming year. While the enterprise plans were legally binding, they were simultaneously supported by incentive designs to comfort and motivate enterprise managers in fulfilling the enterprise plans.

 

·         Gosplan applied some kind of planning-in-stages methods. Two main types of methods were used. In the upper stage, the material balancing method was used to formulate commodity plans, for which the respective ministries carry the responsibility to implement. The material balance method is an iterative process of concurrent adjustment of the supply and demand for each commodity considered, resulting from an exchange of information between Gosplan, ministries and enterprises, and ending when the closing balance shows the sum total of all demands for a commodity equal the sum total of the supply for that commodity. In principle, this balance should hold simultaneously for all commodities considered.

 

 At the lower stage, the investment effectiveness method was used in the selection of expansion projects at the enterprise level. It is placed as a stage below that of material balances where the production targets are determined. Soviet authorities used the investment effectiveness method for choosing among proposed investment projects that expand production capacity of a specific product. The equation can be written as

 

 Ci + rKi = Ai,                                                       (5.1)

 Where,

 Ci = annual operational costs of investment project i;

 Ki = capital costs of investment project i;

Ai = annual total costs of investment project i, and

r = normative rate for discounting capital use, exogenously fixed.

 

The objective is to select projects with the lowest Ai. In periods and sectors in which capital was especially scarce, the value of r was raised. From 1969, a standard value of r = 0.12 was used, although it was sometimes allowed to vary per sector. C, K and A can be eventually specified per unit of production to allow for economies of scale.

 

 

·         We review here the practical operation of the planning system from the points of view of different agents involved in the process, consider the problems they face, how they are affected and the effects of their responses in consecutive order.

 

The Gosplan level: Theoretically speaking, the role which the auctioneer of Leon Walras, or the invisible hand of Adam Smith, plays in bringing equilibrium prices and an efficient allocation of the quantities of goods and resources in the perfect market economy, this same role can be played by the state. In the first place, indivisibilities, uncertainties, externalities and collectivities persist in all economies and make it impossible to reach an efficient allocation. Second, there was no way for the Gosplan of getting all the correct information and processing it. The subordinates may transmit distorted information, unknowingly or on purpose. In the transmission of information, important parts are lost. Third, the Politburo fed the Gosplan with information on its own preferences which were in variance with that of the population at large; as a result, the targeted allocations would be different than the spontaneously desirable allocations of the population and this would cause imbalances in supply and demand. This problem does not occur in competitive markets. Fourth, for specific goods, direct contact between demander and supplier is necessary to settle design questions, and this is impossible to settle at the central level. Also in competitive markets, these specific goods have to be negotiated personally between buyer and seller.

 

The ministry level: In a previous chapter, we made reference to bureaucratic behaviour within ministries, and its distortion effects for the economic process. These apply here too and more significantly.

 

Enterprise managers: The plans were imperative orders and not desirable forecasts. The availability of physical inputs was necessary for achieving the production targets. For the enterprise, it was far more important to obtain an allocation certificate for scarce physical inputs than money. The risk of not securing the physical inputs in time for production of its own output brought tension in the enterprise. The response of the enterprise manager in such a context was varied and betrayed many deficiencies in the planning system. We list here some eight responses. First, frequently, the plans sent by the ministries arrived late at the enterprises, so the enterprises continued to operate on the basis of the old plan. Second, the monitoring of the execution of enterprise plans was weak and the sanctions for counter-actions by the state in case of management failures were limited, for ministerial authorities responsible for the failure would be uncovered as well. So there were tendencies for cover-ups. Third, in a situation of a general scarcity of excellent managers, the state paid managers average bonuses of 25% of their base salary, and reaching 50% for top managers. Fourth, fulfilling the gross output targets was a crucial condition for safeguarding his position as enterprise manager. To do that, he bargained intensely and lobbied for obtaining allocation certificates of inputs, and he use the resources of his office for exchanging favours with local party and state officials. Fifth, alternatively, the enterprise manager may expand his informal delivery network and engage unofficial supply agents in arranging deals in the hidden economy, but he may also neglect assortment targets and adjust quality downwards to meet the quantity targets. Sixth, in communications with the responsible ministry, enterprise managers supplied information that underestimated production capabilities for next year, in this way biasing the ministry to opt for easy gross output targets which the manager can achieve with least effort. Seventh, the state guaranteed that the operations of loss-making public enterprises would be continued nevertheless, a condition known as soft budget constraint. As a result, there was no incentive for the enterprise manager to economize in the use of capital and to minimize on other costs. Finally, in the framework of principal-agency theory, some of the above responses are linked to each other in the context of cross-subsidization, as when the ratcheting of output targets for the better performing enterprises is used to finance the soft budget constraints of the loss-making enterprises. Responding rationally to this cross-subsidization, both enterprises will not maximize their effort and will end up in lower efficiencies.

 

Individual consumers: The overruling of the preferences of the Politburo over the preferences of the consumers manifested itself in the chronic dissatisfaction of the latter, widespread shortages of consumer goods and queues, a limited assortment of goods and services, poor qualities, very slow introduction of new goods.

 

Informal dealers: In the communist regimes, the planned or control economy was often identified as the first economy, in contrast to the second economy that has developed, to the dismay of planners, to resolve imbalances between demand and supply created by plan directives. As was clear from the above accounts, the imbalances arose in the contexts of (a) inter-deliveries among enterprise managers, and (b) sale of scarce goods to individual consumers. Transactions of type (a) arose because it was not easy to fulfil the enterprise plans with the issued allocation certificates of inputs. Enterprise managers often used the services of a tolkach. This was an unofficial supply agent or organization whose job was to see that the necessary materials and equipment would arrive from one enterprise to another. Transactions of type (b) created a small class of market-oriented business people who sold scarce goods and services to affording consumers, such as owners of vehicles providing private transport services; producers of farm products from gardening plots and collective farms; craftsmen fixing repairs privately in exchange in kind, and medical doctors charging more for better treatment.

 

Bureaucratic bias: Economic distortions due to catch and/or corruptive behaviour of bureaucracies and/or enterprises in the actual implementation of regulation rules was discussed in the previous chapter. Economic distortions due to incentive problems commonly encountered in publicly owned and run enterprises, and known as the ratchet constraint, and the soft budget constraint. The ratchet constraint arises in a situation where the ministerial authority (or central planners) fix a future output target for the public enterprise Qt+1 at a higher level than the achieved current output Qt. Calculative managers of the public enterprises will deliberately produce low Qt and pass to the central planners underestimates of their real production to avoid compelling targets. The ratcheting of targets by the central planners creates an X-inefficiency. The soft budget constraint problem applies in situations when the state guarantees that the operations of loss-making public enterprises will be continued nevertheless. As a result, there is no incentive for the public enterprise to economize in the use of capital and to minimize on other costs. The ratchet and the soft budget constraints are incentive problems that are best analyzed in the framework of principal–agency theory. Both constraints are also linked to each other in the context of cross-subsidization, as when the ratcheting of output targets for the better performing enterprises is used to finance the soft budget constraints of the loss-making enterprises. Responding rationally to this cross-subsidization, both firms will not maximize their effort and will end up in lower efficiencies.

Pursued policies and reform strategies

 

(i)                  Pursued policies: On the one hand, they were committed to the socialist aim of maintaining incomes for all citizens at levels sufficient to buy basic goods at cheap prices; this in addition to freely provided collective goods. On the other hand, they were committed to the communist ideology that saw a deepening of capital formation as the development strategy, which would bring success in the longer run. They saw the shortage to be associated with the underdeveloped industry, so they diverted even more of the scarce resources to huge investment programs, resulting in a vicious circle of chronic shortages. The policy makers faced a policy conflict between cheap consumption now and investment now in capital extensive industrial projects with long gestation periods permitting more consumption much later. Whenever they chose for the latter solution, the results were less goods to consume, and greater shortages, now and in the future.

 

The following two equations throw light on the policy conflict. To reach equilibrium, aggregate demand D should equal aggregate supply S. In the communist context, aggregate demand D can be simply written as the wage income, i.e. the average wage W multiplied by number of earners L, less hoarded savings H. The aggregate supply S is the physical quantity of consumer goods Q plus the change in inventories from last year I, these multiplied by the price level of consumer goods P. Note that prices for most consumption goods are based on cost, they are fixed and are hardly affected by imbalances.

D = WL – H                                                                                              (5.3)

 S = (Q + I)P.                                                                                            (5.4)

 

To satisfy the population, the soviet authorities were under pressure to increase wages, and with more earners, the aggregate demand increased appreciably; but as is well known, the physical production of consumer goods Q lagged behind due to reasons of lagging priority and general shortages caused by increasing inefficiencies. At the same time, prices P were not allowed to increase fast enough to absorb the increase in demand. In such circumstances, equilibrium between a demand that is driven by money and a supply that is physically fixed can only be reached by increased hoarding by consumers and a depletion of inventories, implying delayed consumption and repressed inflation. The accumulated tension will turn to be significant in empowering the inflationary pressure, once at some time later, when the economy in transition would allow price liberalization.

 

Conceptually, the ruling class will invest in capital deepening up to a point where its own gains from the last unit invested is equal to its own costs from violating the preferences of the consuming public. So, Soviet leaders responded favourably to consumer grievances between now and then. In the late 1960s, under Khruschev, consumption growth caught up with investment growth, but lagged again from the early 1970s. In the late 1980s, under pressure of public opinion, investment plans were again interrupted to allow for an enhancement of consumer goods. The limited interruptions in investment, which were necessary to satisfy the public, tended to increase gestation lags, postpone production operations of installed capacity, and accentuate the shortages of goods.

 

(ii)                 Reform strategies:  It was observed above that the limitations of the central planning techniques manifest themselves in processing distorted information, delayed and frequent revisions in enterprise plans, disturbances in the production process, wrong deliveries and so on; causing significant losses in labour time that some estimate to amount to 10%. The reforms applied in the 1970s in the SU and Eastern Europe focussed on improving the information structure, planning techniques and incentives. Furthermore, in later years and especially in Eastern Europe, economic reforms were tried with the purposes of introducing commercial considerations in running public enterprises, and integrating the hidden economy with the official economy. The multi-information channels were reduced to two only, those of the ministry and the enterprise. An attempt under Khruschev to decentralize and involve the regional governments was abandoned when he left.

 

Regarding planning techniques, Kosygin introduced greater use of mathematical programming, management information systems and computers. The efforts were effective in shortening the planning process but the pressure for more advanced technologies kept outpacing the introduced efforts. Kosygin reforms have also tackled the incentive problem at the enterprise level. This was done via taut plans. The equation for rewarding the enterprise with a bonus B can be written as

B = aVp + b(Va − Vp),                                                              (5.5)

 

where Vp is the planned value of the bonus forming index that can simply consist of output but can include other indicators as well,

 Va is the actual value for the bonus forming index, and

 a and b are rewards whereby a>b> 0.

 

The first term provides an incentive to adopt a big plan. The bigger the planned value, the higher is the bonus. Besides aiming at taut plans, the second term in the bonus equation encourages the over-fulfillment of plan targets. There is higher weight for the first term than for the second term. The intended result of avoiding the ratchet effect did not work as was anticipated. Instead of mobilizing the hidden reserves of enterprise resources, it strengthened the inclination of enterprise managers to strive for slack plans, that is a smaller Vp, and in a bonus on the second term, while ignoring the bonus on the first term.

 

Just as they did in the 1960s, Soviet leaders under Gorbachev debated the perestroika reform in the mid-1980s with the objective of changing incentives of enterprise managers by relating their rewards to enterprise profitability. This has been defined as the ratio of profits to the stock of capital. The reformer’s hope was that managers would then go for less use of capital, seek efficient production techniques, more innovation and upgrade quality. To let work the reform implied changing the management’s property rights in capital goods. However, to implement the principle of profitability, the Politburo must accept a reduction in its own property rights as regards its authority on the stock of capital held by business firms, and the future pattern of capital formation. This is a conflict in principles, and conflict of interests of rulers versus ruled, which brought the inadequacy of the institutional rules in the communist regime in the open.

 

Finally, some brave attempts of economic reform were tried in Czechoslovakia, Hungary, Poland and the GDR in the late 1950s and 1960s to increase decentralized decision-making at the enterprise level and make it more commercially conscious. But these reforms were doomed to fail at that time due to the absence of four prerequisite conditions. These are microeconomic consistency (this requires that cost calculation, profit maximization, price fixing and competitive bidding should fit to each other and form a harmonious whole), macroeconomic consistency (the input and output outlets, should be readily available and undisturbed by instability and uncertainty), institutional governance that guarantee fairness in case of mischief, and a peaceful and benevolent political environment.

 

Economic performance of the communist regime

·         In terms of the theory of economic systems, agents are inclined to compare the outcomes they receive from the setting in which they are actively working and living, with the outcomes of competing settings. If their system is seen as an underperformer beyond doubt, then they will either transform the foundations of their setting towards the superior one, or if feasible, they will physically move from their system/country to the superior system/country. Obviously, under the communist regime, there were no possibilities for any large-scale movement of people from their country to other countries with brighter prospects. Hence, the drive to abandon the communist foundations became the only alternative left, and to replace them with more successful foundations. The comparatively failing economic performance of the communist regime played a central role in its breakdown.

·         The average annual growth of the GDP, and the GDP per capita, for SIS and FIS-related countries were displayed in Chapter 3. Both groups experienced high growth from 1950 to 1970. The growth of SIS countries started declining in the mid-1970s and reached a standstill in late 1980s.

·         The other measure of the performance of economic systems concerns fairness in the distribution of income and wealth. For what they are worth, various income distribution indicators in Chapter 3 were applied, showing that income was more equally distributed in the SIS than in the FIS countries. Clearly, state property and centrally fixed remuneration levels were the two conditions in the SU that produced a more equitable income.

·         Regarding other performance indicators, unemployment did not exist in an open form in SIS, although hidden underemployment in ministries and enterprises was common. As for inflation, prices were fixed for long periods. After the mid-1970s, sporadic rounds of price increases took place. More significant was the price hike which producers charged to willing consumers for delivery of scarce goods or better quality in the second economy. Important too, was the built-in repressed inflation that took the form of hoarded savings for lack of consumption outlets, and which was the result of pursued allocation policies.

 

Breakdown of the communist regime and the SU 1989–1991

·         Our interpretation of the communist failure is closely linked with Russia’s rise and fall as a world power. The systemic adaptation that took place was geared to the tunes of politically behaving state settings and plans. Because important aspects of the real world could not be incorporated in politically motivated plans, the control system deviated from the real system. We gave examples of deviations between the control and real systems in many areas of economic activity. State agents had to live with these deviations by pursuing hidden conducts that resulted in excluding competition, and creating rents. Such a political behaviour — typical for pure state settings — permits the better-equipped agent to extract and secure a quasi-permanent rent from the less-equipped agent, and it promotes the spread of non-transparent behaviour among non-state agents, making it ultimately the dominant behaviour in the SIS. This political behaviour was reinforced again and again by state settings that behaved politically. When the coverage of a political behaviour extends beyond some threshold, it tends to become the norm that is expected in mutual behaviour, and gains more momentum.

 

·         In a systemic analysis of Russia’s fall, we like to distinguish between internal pressures and external pressures that caused the end of the communist regime.

 

The internal pressures date from around the 1960s to 1970s, when by that time, the population increased significantly and its profile changed appreciably. Demand for more goods, and of a more specific nature, contrasted with a draining up of factors of production. To meet the demands, a shift upward in production possibilities was badly needed. The apparent harmony that characterized the first few decades of the communist regimes cracked from the 1970s onwards. With contradictions between the control and real worlds increasing, and the same old policies continuing; inefficiencies, waste and shortages multiplied, leading to reductions in overall growth.

 

The external pressures increased appreciably in the 1970s and 1980s. As the closed regimes gradually opened up, their public was in a position to compare and evaluate their performance versus that of neighbouring market economies, and come to the evaluation that their regime performed less. In terms of the theory of economic systems, the evaluation leads to three options. The first option is to remain loyal to the regime in the hope that promises made will one day materialize; some did that, but in relative terms that was only a very small minority. The second and third options are either to exit or to voice. Possibilities of exit were extremely limited, even though some outflow took place from East to West Germany.

 

·         Pejovic (1982), extended in Pejovic (2001), maintains that the original terms of contract between the Politburo and the Soviet people lost validity due to the realization that the Marxist thesis that socialism is a historically superior system to capitalism is refuted in view of the proven lower performance of socialism as compared to capitalism.

·         Eggersston (1990), close to Winiecki (1986), place their interpretation within the analytical frameworks of agency problems, transaction costs and property rights. They argue that (a) the managers of state enterprises respond to incentives which discourage cost minimization, and (b) the organizational structure of state enterprises have not adapted to technological developments, resulting in rising transaction costs. The solution of these problems would require replacing the command by prices, i.e. writing off the communist regime and instituting a profit-maximizing market economy. A competitive market for managers would represent a huge transfer of wealth away from party functionaries who hold property rights at the managerial levels. Hence, is the opposition of party cadres to meaningful reforms.

·         Stiglitz (1993) focuses on problems of incentives and information in his interpretation of the communist failure. The interpretation of Stiglitz fits neatly within the principal–agency analytical framework. The principal is the planning bureaucrat while the agent is the enterprise manager. Bureaucrats did not possess the requisite information to know how to allocate resources efficiently. Managers of firms had no incentive to tell the bureaucrats what the minimum inputs required to meet their production goals were.

 

RECESSION AND RECOVERY



The recessions of 4–10 years depending on the transition economy wiped on average about 40% of the GDP of the pre-transition period, but this average hides significant difference, as Table 5.2 shows that output has fallen in BCEE by about 31% on average by the time it bottomed out. By 2000, six countries have recovered back their loss in the GDP, and by 2005, 11 of the 12 reported BCEE countries have recovered the GDP loss. The magnitude of the recession in RRTC is much higher with an average loss in the real GDP of 60% in the lowest year of GDP as compared to 1988. The XSIR group occupies a middle position with an average loss of 49% in their worst year. Recovery followed, but as Column 6 shows, the GDP of BCEE is better off in 2005 compared to 1988 by +14% (with Poland scoring +56%), RRTC are less off by about −11% (Russia scoring worse at −14%). The XSIR occupy middle positions with a loss of −3% (oil-rich Kazakhstan scored +10%).

·        When countries change from one system to another they go through heavy adjustments that reduce activity now but can promise more growth in the future. The decline was severe and varied appreciably per country group. What are the causes of the downfall in production? And how do these causes apply to the three groups of transition countries? Two major causes are behind the downfall: system disorientation and transition policies.

·        System disorientation in Russia took various forms.

 (a) Plan instructions, supported by informal networks on deliveries of intermediate inputs, ceased to be obligatory as the old system collapsed, leading to a melting down of obligations to mutual delivery between enterprises and to a widespread inter-industrial supply defaults and production decline.

 (b) Laws requiring self-financing caused a credit crunch that held production back.

 (c) Financial arrears between enterprises, based on real production deliveries that could not take place, accumulated and there was no mechanism to settle them, resulting in the obstruction of input deliveries for regular production plans.

 (d) Bank managers, in control of supplying credit, favoured enterprises from which they profited most at a personal level, thus leading to misallocations, and a deadweight loss in production.

 (e) Confusion and uncertainty encouraged expropriation of public enterprises by managers and ministries, and subsequent foreign flight of appropriated capital, reducing investment and production further.

(f) Labour inputs diminished as people encountered shortages, political confusion and discouraged work appetite. Enterprises diverted their reserves to buying consumption necessities for their workers, at the cost of provisions for investment and production.

 (g) Regions, anticipating shortages, took measures to restrict mobility of goods to other regions, thus causing production bottlenecks in all regions.

 

·         A few observations are in place on the differentiated transition policies. At an early phase of the transition, repressed inflation and hoarded savings, especially in Russia, contributed to an excess of money over the value of goods demanded and available. The monetary overhang drove prices up. Besides, once prices were made free to move, they soared under a shockoriented price liberalization strategy. The fiscal budget balance deteriorated due to falls in revenue and insufficient cuts in expenditures. Simultaneously, the foreign payments balance was destabilized by huge currency devaluations. Pushed by political unrest and capital flight, the Russian rubble fell to 1/10th of its pre-transition level.

 

In a next phase of the transition, firms needed finance and workers demanded more wages in the face of rising prices. Most of the BCEE transition economies did not give into the demand for issuing more money, and kept wages within temporary control. They held tight credit and sharp cuts in subsidies. In BCEE, the fiscal deficit went down to around 6%. This is to be compared with Russia’s 12%, and the other ex-Soviet countries, which were in between. Currencies of most BCEE reforming countries recovered in foreign exchange value due to remarkable export growth and trade surpluses. Russia and the other ex-Soviet countries went the opposite way and were generous in the money supply growth and net domestic credit, which grew by 150-fold during 1992–1994. The growth of this credit to dubious enterprises and clients at negative real interest rates in Russia has been interpreted in terms of rent-seeking and corruption practices between a too closely linked government to enterprises. Moreover, Russia experienced a series of foreign exchange crises that retarded investment and growth furthermore.

 

·         The recession in BCEE was shorter followed by a quicker recovery/the recession in XSIR and Russia is extended to 1995 and 1998, respectively. The BCEE group contained countries that are economically more advanced than XSIR and Russia. BCEE countries situated close to the EU have gone through reforms that were directed towards their eventual integration in the EU, and had the benefit of a larger inflow of foreign assistance per head than countries of the former SU. Weak oil prices did not help Russia, and the war in Chechnya diverted resources to non-productive uses.

 

THE SHORT TRANSITION AND THE LONG TRANSITION

·         Transitional reforms can be broken down between those occurring during a short and a long transition.

 The short transition took on average 2 to 3 years, and focused on macroeconomic stabilization and microeconomic liberalization (i.e. deregulation of product markets and privatization of state-owned production factors, in particular, small enterprises).

 

The long transition, which is a restructuring phase that requires a decade or more to get the economy on track, concentrates on resolving market failures in a transition economy, and thus deals with (a) extended deregulation of factor markets, extended privatization of state enterprises and institutionalizing market competition; (b) increasing market confidence; (c) internalizing inherited externalities; (d) balanced provisions of public goods; and (e) sustained financing of income maintenance for those in need.

 

·         ‘gradual change’ strategy or a ‘sudden shock’ strategy: Hungary, Slovenia, Slovakia, Romania are considered to have followed a gradual change approach. Poland went for the sudden shock. Other countries in the BCEE group manifested a mix between the two manners. In contrast, Russia and all republics of the ex-SU have initiated their transition in a sudden shock environment.

 

STRENGTHENING COMPETITIVENESS IN MARKETS AND STATE

·        When government sells shares of privatized companies to the general public at the stock exchange, or organizes a competitive sale among contending buying companies, or a takeover in an investment fund, domestically or foreign, the resulting enterprise governance tends to be an outsider governance. When the method of privatization takes the form of management– employee buyouts, the resulting enterprise governance is insider governance. This applies also in case of a partial privatization when the state owns a major share and mobilizes a selected financial group to own remaining shares. The privatization of state enterprises that occurred in the recent past in Western Europe were of the outsider type, privatization in the transition economies of Eastern Europe followed a mixture of outsider and insider governance with more emphasis on the latter.

·        The privatization modes pursued promoted outsider governance in BCEE, and insider governance in RRTC and XSIR. BCEE transferred about 28% of state ownership to outside owners, and thus departed from insider governance (Hungary and Estonia transferred about 40% of state ownership to outside owners). The Czechs Republic distributed equal access vouchers to citizens, which is also primarily an outsider governance-oriented policy.  Poland combined transferring ownership to outsiders with transfers to municipalities and semi-public bodies that maintained strong links between management and state. In contrast, the Russian government’s management buyouts were a choice for insider governance. This has been rationalized on the grounds that Russia had no stock markets to float initial public offers, the public lacks purchasing power, there are no high performing domestic companies to take over the ailing state enterprises, and selling to foreign companies was felt to be against the national interest and would raise unsolvable negotiations on asset valuation. The position of insiders was strengthened furthermore by the 1998 financial crisis, as their potential challengers — domestic and foreign outside investors — lost the ability or appetite to invest in Russian firms.

 


 

Chapter 6 ECONOMIC SYSTEMS IN THE DEVELOPMENT REGIONS

 

·        In considering a more historic and regional scope, we have proposed in Chapter 3 to distinguish between six development regions comprising East Asia and Pacific (EAP), South Asia (SA), Central Asia and Caspian (CAC), Middle East and North Africa (MENA), Sub Saharan Africa (SSA) and Latin America and Caribbean (LAC).


The EAP region, consisting of China, Indonesia, Philippines, Vietnam and others in East Asia and the Pacific, is positioned close to the HIS corner, but also along the HIS–FIS axis, reflects the two facts that the majority of agents in the region are still in rural areas where household settings are dominant, and that sizable populations have already moved to and are living in urban cities during a relatively short period of high economic growth; this population manifests the impact of firm settings.

 

 The SA region consisting of India, Bangladesh, Pakistan, Sri Lanka, among others is placed in the HIS corner, which reflects the relatively high dominance of household settings in this region. The region lies also on the HIS–FIS axis but affiliation with FIS in SA is less than in EAP.

 

 The CAC region has become a vital region in the last three decades with the strengthened roles of Turkey and Iran in the region and the access of the ex-Soviet Islamic Republics to this region, among them some oil-rich countries like Kazakhstan and Azerbaijan. The state has strong authoritarian rule which is reflected in positioning CAC closer to SIS than HIS.

 

The MENA region is practically speaking, the Arab countries, led by Egypt and Saudi Arabia among others. They are placed halfway the HIS–SIS axis, in view of histories and traditions that have largely stayed intact, and by which households voluntarily entrust state leadership. The region includes some oil-rich Arab Gulf countries modern business segments, bringing them close to firm settings.

The SSA region, led by diverse countries such as Nigeria, Ethiopia, South Africa, Angola and including a total of 48 countries is positioned close to the household settings, HIS corner, as kinship and ethnic ties are well known to occupy a central role in agent interaction in most African countries. SSA lies also on the HIS–SIS axis in view of the quick rise of state authorities as powerful players after gaining independence.

 

 Finally, the LAC region, led by Brazil and Mexico and including a total of 41 countries, is positioned along the HIS–FIS axis, but closer to FIS than HIS, reflecting long periods of a significant impact of firm settings on the economic system, and a relatively higher degree of urbanization than other developing countries.

 

TIMELINE OF DEVELOPMENT EPOCHS

·         We distinguish six historical epochs and speculate on their effects on the subsystems. The historical epochs are: (1) colonial rule, (2) nation building, (3) democratic reforms, (4) demographic transition, (5) economic development and (6) global integration. Epochs 1–3 are loaded with political events; while epochs 4–6 are more driven by economic forces. The table distinguishes between the rural and urban locations of household, firm and state settings in an analysis of the systemic impacts of the various historical epochs.


 

·        The resulting colonial configurations between the colonizer and the impacted country can be described to have evolved over time towards four forms that ranged from (a) a fully absorbed commonwealth country, to (b) settled colonies, (c) occupied colonies and (d) loosely linked strategic relationships with autonomous regions.

 

The first form is that of the fully absorbed commonwealth countries, such as US, Canada and Australia. Very large European migrations took place to these countries, allowing them to form, in a relatively short time, the over majority of the total population. Soon afterwards, they went for nationhood and independence in the 17th and 18th centuries; and remained closely affiliated to their European ancestors and institutions.

 

The second form is that of regions settled by migrants, and supported by armies, but nevertheless with substantial native populations working in mining and plantations, and residing in rural areas, such as in Latin America. . Realization of nationhood and independence in these countries took more time to mature, i.e. in the 19th century.

 

The third form took the shape of army-occupied and annexed colonies, and applied to many countries in Asia and Africa. There was no permanent role for colonial settlers, instead there were relatively limited numbers of foreign soldiers and related officials who maintained the colonial rule. The colonial epoch endured longer in this category than in the other categories, and the accomplishment of political independence was mostly accompanied with resistance and wars of liberation.

 

The fourth form was based on relationships of a more calculative nature that emerged between the colonial powers and autonomously run countries that have remained politically and economically independent of the rest of the world. One can include here bigger countries such as Japan and China, but also much smaller and distanced Islamic countries such as Iran and the Arab peninsula. It is somewhat striking that in spite of the absence of a colonized history in these countries, their economic systems have undergone more fundamental changes than others due to other historical interactions such as the global integration of Japan, the communist revolution in China and oil discovery in Central Asia and the Middle East.

 

Focusing on the developing world, we have argued above that the colonial epoch had its largest impact on host countries in category (b), much less in (c) and very least in (d).

 

·         Colonial rule had to give way to national independence. With the advent of national independence, in one country after another, political authority was transferred from colonial powers to national governments guarded by elite leaders.

 

 National independence, identity and integration, usually described as nation building, was the driving force for the first round of governments in the developing world.

A significant role was created for the state, via reorganization and creation of centralized governmental institutions and civil and administrative rules, an extension of the bureaucracy to assist and control, assignment of prominent roles for police and military defence capabilities, using media in focalizing the state and state officials, and emphasis on national sentiment and allegiance to the nation state. As a result, the state gained influence in most developing countries.

 

 However, in some countries, these state actions generated counteracting forces that contradicted the very nature of nation building, brought civil divides and resulted in weakening the institutions of the state subsystem. In the EAP region, Cambodia is the foremost example. In the SA region, the split up of Pakistan was the foremost example. Ethnic exclusion has been a major cause of civil violence in the Middle East with foremost examples being Iraq and Syria. In some African countries, i.e. Nigeria, Burundi, Congo, Rwanda and Sudan this type of conflict led to civil violence and in some cases to civil war with winning and losing groups.

 

In other countries, the military disintegrated and collided with affiliated ethnic groups in self-defence or in search of dominance over others, i.e. Afghanistan in SA, Syria and Iraq in MENA and Angola, Congo DR, Liberia, Mali, Mozambique, Sudan and Somalia in SSA.

 

Finally, ideological confrontations between conformists and reformers disrupted the stability of national governments in many countries of the developing world and tended to have mixed effects on the focalizing of the state in the system.

 

·         More recently, more countries have adopted parliamentary elections and majority rules, these being political solutions that are the most logical if violence is to be avoided in reaching political compromises between different factions.  Table shows the share of authoritarian regimes has declined from 73 to 31%, while the share of multiparty democracies increased from 15 to 53%. By the turn of the 20th to the 21st century, the shift towards democratic institutions is seen to be highest in the Latin American region, followed by the Asian, African and Arab regions.

 

·         Household-led demographic transition: Demographic transition refers to the transition from high birth rates and death rates to low birth and death rates in the process of economic development. In due course, as households move from rural to urban areas, and become subjected to modernization, education, emancipation, rising incomes and considerations of opportunity cost, the reproduction behaviour of households changes towards smaller size families; and thus causing birth rates to decline.

 

·         State-led economic development: In a nutshell, economic development required structural transformation from an agricultural into an industrializing economy, and from a closed to an open economy, with due attention to both the enhancement of agriculture and of building viable industries capable of becoming net exporters in competitive world markets. The structural transformation required raising and upgrading the factors of production of capital and labour to assure a greater production on the supply side, and an expansion of purchasing power to assure an equal balance on the demand side.

 

Removal of labour from agriculture to industry will not hurt agriculture, and will moderate the wage rate in industry and attract industrial investment. The transformation from agriculture to industry was seen to require a shift of labour and capital (forced savings) from the first to the second sector. Building an industrial infrastructure and providing industrial capital requires taking capital (either voluntarily or via forced savings) away from agriculture and invest it in industry. If the capital is to be channelled voluntarily, then this would mean that rich landholders would directly or indirectly become industrial investors. When the channel is that of forced savings, this can be done centrally via state nationalization of agriculture, like in China, or in decentralized ways via tax levies and via state boards purchasing agricultural crops from farm producers at lower prices and selling at higher prices, like in India and other developing countries; the proceeds are then invested by the state in the development of industry. Because rich landholders in most developing countries at the time were not well prepared or willing for industrial entrepreneurship, this meant that the state had to take the responsibility of collecting forced savings from agriculture and investing them in industry.

 

With respect to industry, it was accepted by policy advisors that a takeoff required next to skill formation and capital deepening, an investment programme across all industrial sectors that makes use of industrial linkages and economies of scale.

 

 The striking of a balance between incentives for export promotion and import substitution, which generates high levels of net foreign exchange, is a major challenge for he state’s management of economic development. The protection of infant industries by restricting imports was seen as an intermediate step in a strategy of export promotion. In principle, import protection and foreign trade regulations are supposed to be temporary, and are to be phased away as the concerned industry realizes its comparative export advantage.

 

·         Firm-led economic development: Nevertheless, in some large and small countries, there was the realization that the time was ripe to reduce state regulations, liberalize the economy and encourage private business to integrate with the world economy through exports and more reliance on foreign direct investment (FDI). These countries played leading roles in attracting other countries to follow suit. The first country to take such a leading role was Japan immediately after WWII, followed later by Korea, Singapore, Taiwan and Hong Kong in the 1970s. Among the development regions, it was China in EAP that shifted gear in 1980 and opened opportunities for private firms to expand outwards. In SA, economists tend to agree that India started this process in the 1990s.

 

In CAC, Turkey is acclaimed to having entered the firm-led economic development in the late 1970s. In MENA, Israel aside, the obvious example is the United Arab Emirates, and a couple of neighbouring Arab Gulf countries, whose economic development was fully firm-led since its establishment in 1971, though there are significant participations of the ruling authorities in the governance structures of leading firms in the country. Other countries in MENA are still functioning with a predominantly state-led development orientation.

The SSA region is very diverse. There are huge firm-led bilateral ventures in mineral-rich African countries, though their operations are rather enclave. Most other African countries have maintained and strengthened their state subsystem.

 

WB circles tend to signal Ghana as one of the first African countries to move from a state-led to a firm-led economic development, but Kenya qualifies as well.

 

Although firm-led economic development is anchored in the LAC region, the influence of the state subsystem tended to go up and down in various countries and at various times. Cuba, Bolivia, Nicaragua and Venezuela are the conventional examples of LAC countries leaning towards a state-led economic development.

 

WB circles pose the liberalization measures of the 1970s and 1980s in Mexico, and Chile, and later on Colombia and Brazil, as major steps in the bolstering a firm-led outward development. Other LAC countries followed suit.

 

·         Globalization-led and firm-led integration with the world economy:  It was stated earlier that the pace of economic development depends significantly on the availability of foreign exchange, which is obtainable via exports of goods and services, and via foreign financial flows in the forms of official development assistance (ODA), net foreign loan transfers (FLT), and net foreign direct investment (FDI).

 

The share of exports from developing countries in total world exports increased from 16% in 1990 to 20% in 2000 and to 34% in 2012. With respect to foreign financial flows, the prominence of ODA in the early development decades gave way to foreign loans and foreign investment in latter decades. While practically all regions experienced declines in their shares in world ODA over the years, SSA increased its share and has become in recent years the major recipient of ODA with about a quarter of the total ODA in 2012. The flow of net FLT, which was previously positive, reversed direction into net transfers of foreign debt repayments from the late 1980s onwards, mostly due to debt repayments that were higher than fresh loans and investment booms creating financial crises; this applied particularly for the LAC and EAP regions. In contrast, net FDI has become by the turn of the century the dominant force in the financial global integration of development regions, with the EAP and LAC regions as the main beneficiaries.

 

The greater openness of an economy to the international financial markets makes it usually vulnerable at times to serious financial crises. In LAC, this occurred in 1982 when Mexico was unable to meet its obligations to pay foreign debts after an over-borrowing spree in preceding years. Fearful of risk of default payment, international lending banks reduced their financial flows to defaulting and other countries in LAC and beyond. This combined with a surge in oil prices led to a slow economic growth in most development regions for a couple of years.

 

The vulnerability of the integrating developing economies in unstable world financial markets reappeared again in EAP in 1998, when the devaluation of the Thailand currency was followed by other devaluations in the EAP, downfalls in stock markets and withdrawals of foreign financial resources from the region.18 The confidence crisis was fuelled by the lack of transparency in corporate governance and state dealings, and a future economic outlook that was seen to be bleak against the background of over-expanded investment in construction and other production capacities.

 

REASSESSMENT OF STRUCTURAL CHANGE AND DEVELOPMENT PERFORMANCE

 

·        In development economics, we are used to focus on the positive change in factor productivity as factors move from the less productive agriculture to the more productive industry. System economics would highlight the shift in agent behaviour from the household sharing type to the profit maximizing type as more and more agents move from the household subsystem H (say agriculture as a proxy) to the firm subsystem F (industry as proxy). The shift of agents and value added from agriculture to industry, next to causing rises in productivity and growth, constitute the reset of pursued preferences, and a remix of behavioural types in favour of that of F at the cost of that of H. Our reset shifts focus from sectors to subsystems, which is a richer notion in the analysis of economic systems. The F subsystem has its own subsystem dynamics supported by institutions facilitating free entry of business entrepreneurs and market competition. A subsystem overshadows and extends much beyond the economist’s conventional focus on sectors of economic activity.

·        How do agents get engaged in producing services fare in this approximation? They form a mixture of

 (a) informally operating households that rely mostly on self-employed and family workers and thus associate with the household subsystem;

 (b) formally operating firms that maximize profit and where the mode of employment is that of employer–employee;

(c) a fluent combination of the informal and formal modes and

 (d) employment in the public sector.

 

Rough estimates for the developing world suggest that over half or more of agents delivering services are found in the informal household settings relating to (a), the other half is spread on (b), (c) and (d), whereby public sector employees are often higher than the formally engaged service workers in the private sector.

·        The two indicators we shall use for representing state influence relate to agent participation and transformed value added in the public sector. One indicator we use is the share of public revenue in the GDP. Measured at the regional level, this share ranged between 11 and 31% for the development regions in 2012, being lowest in the Asian regions and highest in MENA, reflecting a greater influence of the state in the Arab countries than in other regions. The share has been rising in all regions between 2000 and 2012, by some 4% on the average.

 

The other indicator attempts to construct the share of public employment in total employment. A study by the International Labour Office (ILO), Hammouya (1999), contains estimates based on an ILO survey questionnaire carried out in 1995–1997 for a small number of the larger developing countries with which we are primarily concerned, and a larger number of tiny countries that matter less. The estimates would suggest that the share of public employees in total wage and salary paid employees in this period amounted to 36% in China, 70% in India and averages of 38% in MENA, 5.5% in SSA and 12% in LAC.22 The data surveyed by the study are very scanty and too static for our purpose. However, the survey showed a high concentration of public employees in the services sector, reaching an average of 83% for the developing countries (in Brazil 95%); a fact which we can build upon.

For lack of alternative indicators, we propose to construct and apply an equivalent indicator for the share of public employees in total employment defined as (employment in services/total employment) × (public revenue/GDP). This indicator should not be read as the absolute share of public employment in total employment in the country concerned; it cannot give that. The values of the indicator should be viewed as indicative of where and when the state is more or less influential, when then indicator is applied for comparisons between countries and over time. Note that share of public revenue/GDP is a direct determinant of state influence, but it is also embodied in the specification of the share of public employees in total employment.






·         The GDP growth achieved in a specific country can be viewed as the result of

 (a) available factors of production that went into producing the GDP, and

 (b) the efficiency degree accomplished in the system wise utilization of these factors of production, i.e. the growth in factor productivity.

 

While (a) falls under country specific data, (b) is an efficiency notion that is tied to the organizational setup of the economic system.

 

 Growth accounting decomposition allows separating the effect of the country-specific factors of production, from the effect of factor productivity which is system specific. We shall apply growth accounting decompositions to separate country specific effects from system specific effects.

 

·         Table 6.11, Columns 1 to 2, give GDP growth in 1960–2000 and 2000– 2012, showing the two Asian regions of EAP and SA as best performers. This is partially accounted for by significant structural transformations from agriculture to industry in both regions, as well as early and stronger shifts from import protection to export promotion in EAP and later in SA. Growth accounting decompositions add insight over differences between the development regions regarding determinants of economic growth. Such an analysis is feasible for the period 1960–1994, Table 6.11, Columns 3–6.

For EAP, the annual GDP growth of 6.8% over the years 1960–1994 is accounted for by a country effect of 5.7% (annual growth in factors of production labour and capital were 2.3%, and 3.4%) and a systemic effect of 1.3% (an annual growth in total factor productivity accounted for the remaining 1.3%). The contribution of systemic effecting SA is 17% (that is, 0.8%/4.6%). Efficiency growth in SA contributed 19% as well (i.e. 0.8/4.2).

·         Proceeding from growth of GDP to growth of GDP per capita (GDP pc), these are reduced after neutralizing for demographic trends, which are for a part due to uncontrolled nature and for a part due to system control. The reduction due to demographic growth is least in EAP (8.0 − 8.9 = −0.9), which is partly due to system-controlled demographic growth, i.e. China. Compare with SA where the reduction is bigger due to uncontrolled nature (5.2 − 6.8 = −1.6).

 

It is noted that these growth rates of the GDP pc are based on consolidated regional totals of the GDP and population. These rates can be higher than the mean growth rates of the GDP pc, Column 2, which are calculated as non-weighed means of countries in the region. For instance, the total growth rate of EAP of 8.0%, largely due to China’s growth rate of 9.4%, is reduced to a mean growth rate of 4.7% because countries included like Philippines and Malaysia had growth rates of only 2.9% and 2.8%.


How did the development regions combine higher well-being (that is growth in GDP pc) with performance on the dimension of income distribution (this is measured by such indicators as the Gini index and other ratios of income concentration)?

 

Another relevant indicator of income inequality is the ratio of income shares of the richer top 20% of the population (T20%) to the poorer bottom 20% of the population (B20%). This indicator modified to apply to 10% of the population (that is T/B 10%) shows even greater tendencies towards income inequality. 

 

 

 

·         Development economics states that GDP growth is achieved as labour (and other factors of production) shift from low to high productivity activities, that earn more, thus causing a rise in income inequality. This initial rise need not be overwhelming or permanent since the achieved higher well-being would subsequently increase the demand for all earners, and upgrade those with a low to a higher productivity, thus reducing or eliminating the initial rise in income inequality. This being the normal path in received theory, it follows that the quantifiable difference between the observed and the normal path is accountable to the socio-economic system in which economic development takes place.

 

COUNTRY VARIATIONS WITHIN REGIONS

·        We shall discuss structural and performance features of the six leading countries in each region, which is sufficiently wide to give a representative picture of regional diversity.

 

·        East Asia Pacific (EAP):   States and firms in countries of the EAP tend often to see the development formula followed by Japan and Korea followed as ideal models of economic development that are applicable and adaptable to their developing economies. The development formula of these economies is outward industrialization. This required the ending of centuries of feudal agriculture, the swift reallocation of labour, capital and purchasing power from agriculture to industry and services and the mobilization of these forces in expanding merchandise exports to, and attracting foreign investment from the richer and more developed economies.

 

Once the basics for the take-off was established, China encroached on a stepwise diminished dependence on state enterprises in favour of private business, and a controlled but extensive orientation towards foreign trade and joint ventures. In a similar vein, Vietnam followed a largely calculated development course. Other major countries in EAP such as Indonesia, Philippines, Malaysia and Thailand followed more spontaneous development courses and had less control on the pace of their outward industrialization. This permitted a greater dependence of their national economies on foreign finance, which made them more susceptive to risky international financial transactions, showing itself in the Asian financial crises that started from a distrust by international financial institutions in corporate and banking commitments in Thailand in 1997–1998, and spread to other ASEAN countries, causing a recession in these countries, with a duration of 3 to 5 years. EAP includes other countries and other small territories and islands that lag behind, some of them can be described to be still in the pre-phase of a take-off and are not yet in the stage of an outward industrialization.

Although political authority is highly esteemed, the size of government (that is the public share) is kept relatively low in EAP. Development policy has been of the targeted type with coordination between business and state at high levels and in specific sectors that are considered strategic.

 

·         South Asia (SA):  The inward-oriented economic development and the reliance on state enterprises, regulation and planning, typical of the 1950s–1970s, strengthened political power of the state, but did not eliminate the soft state character. Starting from the late 1980s, state policy emphasized more outward-oriented outlook, greater reliance on private enterprises and reduced state intervention. The deregulation reforms and the efforts towards global integration proceeded later in SA than in EAP.

 

Traditionally, the state in the SA region has been often described as a soft state due to the strength of the feudally oriented customary household subsystem and state capture by feudal leaders. While these features were more prominent in the past, they have managed to survive though at a lower degree.

 

·         Central Asia and Caspian (CAC):  The CAC region comprises the two large countries of Turkey and Iran and six smaller ex-Soviet Union Islamic Republics, XSIR. Four of the eight countries are oil rich. Turkey and Iran dominate the region. All eight countries share religious belief, cultural heritage, attitudinal traits and similar external environments. The region is probably the most homogeneous group among the six development regions.

 

In spite of this high income growth, the Gini index has fallen on average. The underlying tendency of higher growth with more equality is a systemic property that applies generally to all countries of the region, and stands in remarkable contrast with most developing countries which generally show higher growth with less equality.

 

·         Middle East and North Africa (MENA):   MENA, as defined in this book, is practically speaking the ‘Arab world’. This description does not automatically mean the MENA region is economically a homogeneous group of countries. Just as in the case of CAC, there are oil-rich countries cooperating together in the Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC), and non-GCC non-oil countries which constitute the over majority of the population but a relatively smaller share of the GDP of MENA. GCC countries have relocated their agricultural labour force (and their customary household settings) to urban employment long ago. In GCC, the firm subsystem has grown rapidly, but its establishment as an institutional subsystem comparable to those found in FIS countries is still far ahead.

 

While the F subsystem is significantly diversified in MENA, the common feature for the MENA is the relatively high shares of public revenue and public spending in the GDP, and their applicability for all countries in the region.

 

·         Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA):  Prior to and during colonial rule, kinship settings dominated life in SSA. When newly emerging commercial firms and state agencies started functioning in the SSA environment, it was imperative that their structure, conduct and performance would manifest the allegiance of agents to kin groups. Kin groups will attempt to favour their own members in the assignment of jobs in firms or government, and the allocation of other benefits and costs. While kinship settings have efficiency advantages in minimizing transaction costs among its members, the same kinship settings have efficiency costs when favouritism leads to misallocation of physical and human resources. When ethnic favouritism spreads to state settings, the probability is high that civil discontent, disorder and violence accelerate. The positive associations between ethnic fractionalization, political instability and economic underperformance are highest for the SSA region, when compared with other development regions. The functioning of firm and state settings in SSA are thus embedded within a behavioural system that prioritize the value of kin relations and loyalty.

 

The region contains a very large number of countries: 48 countries. To obtain a grip on the diversity of countries, it is helpful to subdivide the region roughly into an upper belt that corresponds roughly with the Sahel lines consisting of 24 countries and a lower belt below the Sahel that is consisting of 24 countries. The upper belt is more arid and is subjected to more desertification when compared to the more temperate and water-rich lower belt. Although both belts are rich in natural resources, these are less exploited in the upper than the lower belt. While the upper belt is more Islamic, the lower belt is more Christian. The upper belt had less in-migration of labour and capital from other countries and colonial settlements than the lower belt. France was more present as a colonial power in the upper belt, Britain more in the lower belt.

 

French is more spread in the upper belt, English in the lower belt. The decolonizing of the upper belt and achievement of national independence in these countries occurred quite peacefully, compared to various wars of independence and liberation in most countries of the lower belt. All these circumstances taken together have resulted in an upper belt that is economically less developed and poorer than the lower belt. But there are significant exceptions (in the upper belt, Nigeria in the upper belt is rich in oil and well off, Ethiopia is least; in the lower belt, South Africa is richest, while Congo DR is mineral rich but strikingly poor).

 

·         Latin America and Caribbean (LAC):   Although North America (in reference to USA and Canada) and South America were discovered and populated at around the same time, they have become two totally different environments: an economically advanced and rich USA and Canada, and a development region of LAC consisting of 33 developing countries. Explanations for the different courses abound: geographical distance of LAC to Europe is longer, timing and scale of people and capital moving to LAC was later, colonists who settled in LAC were less entrepreneurial, the struggle for independence in LAC was five decades later than that of USA, attempts after independences at uniting LAC failed while USA succeeded, adherence to passed constitutions and the rule of law in LAC countries was very weak compared to USA. The current huge material gap between LAC and US is also directly explainable in terms of socio-economic and political barriers in LAC that stand in the way of intensive communication between populations placed in stratified socio-economic classes.

 

Mexico is the dominant leader in the upper belt which consists of small Caribbean countries; while Brazil is dominant in the lower belt in terms of population and GDP, followed by Argentina and Colombia. Indicators of state influence show a more pronounced role of the state in the lower belt than in the upper belt. As regards indicators of global links, the share of export/GDP is higher in Mexico than Brazil, Argentina and Colombia. In contrast, the share of FDI/GDP is higher in the later countries.

 

PATTERNS OF CONVERGENCE AND DIVERGENCE

·        What kind of significance should be attached to the difference between US$ and PPP$? A PPP exchange rate equalizes the purchasing power of different currencies in their home countries for a given basket of goods. It is a better measure of standards of living between countries, more so than GDP pc in US$. Because the share of non-traded goods and services, and their prices, are lower in countries with lower income levels, the standard of living of poorer countries is raised and that of richer countries lowered when PPP$ is used instead of US$.41 As a result, the gap in the income per capita between richer and poorer regions is reduced remarkably when PPP$ is applied.

 

APPENDICES

Page num: 287-300

 


 Chapter 7 FOCUS ON CHINA AND INDIA AS UPCOMING GLOBAL LEADERS

DISPLACEMENT CALCULUS

·        The displacement calculus was first brought to popular attention by the so-called BRIC report. The BRIC model by Wilson and Purushothaman (2003) was a first attempt to use simple country models, for Brazil, Russia, India and China among others, hence BRIC, to examine likely displacement scenarios for major countries. The BRIC model sees emerging economies catching up with and overrunning industrial economies due to (a) higher real growth in GDP expressed in real US$, and (b) growing appreciation of their national currencies, as a country’s market exchange rate against the US$ in the future converges towards its purchasing power parity (PPP).




·        The forecasts obtained for 2040 and 2050 were startling at the time they were issued. BRIC-2003 forecasted in 2003 that China and India will pass the US and Japan due to both a and b. China and US were forecasted to have equal shares of the world GDP, about 23%, in 2040, but China would surpass US by some 5 percentage points in 2050. By then, India would surpass EU by 4 percentage points. The top four countries in 2050 would be China, US, India and EU, with the following GDP shares: 26.0, 20.6, 16.3 and 10.4. These four big countries would be followed by the group of four smaller countries of Japan, Russia, Brazil and Mexico with GDP ratios varying between 3 and 4%. However, the gaps in the income per capita between the richer western countries and others would remain, though lower.

·        Today, the projected displacement timeline of BRIC-2003 is best described as outdated when compared with the latest revisions, for instance PWC (2013), which use the same BRIC model but with more updated and accumulated data, and improves on methods applied for forecasts of foreign exchange rates. The PWC forecasts show the displacement to occur much earlier than was thought. It is predicted that the GDP of China would overpass the GDP of US in 2017, in terms of PPP and by 2027, in terms of market exchange rates. India would come close to US in 2050, and a long way ahead of the next batch of medium-sized countries.



 

·        China and India are recorded to have been leading economies in the world until about the 18th century. After two centuries of downfall, their economies have risen again and are forecasted to regain their leading positions by 2040. After 2040, the growth rate in India’s GDP is forecasted to be higher than that of China’s GDP. The then would-be-held expectations of the relative future prospects of the two economies could play a significant role in determining the future courses of the two economies. The displacement of world leadership is comparable in significance to the ages of discoveries and the industrial revolution. The growth of the FIS and its spread to other countries in the 20th century was driven and shaped by the US, EU, and Japan being its largest contenders. If in the 21st century, the economies of US, EU and Japan are on the retreat as world leaders, then the FIS as we know it today in the FIS-centred countries is also likely to retreat, be modified or be outgrown by the prototype economic systems that associate with the newly emerging world leaders. It defies prediction and relevance to discuss whether the multi-poles system (MPS), will be realized, and if so whether MPS will replace the firm intensive system (FIS), as the forerunner in the 21st or 22nd century, or that some synthesis will emerge. But modifications in FIS so as to accommodate and adapt elements of the MPS (like persuasion settings and consensus coordination, and likely more than these two elements) are almost certain due to the more rapidly growing interactive and regulative influences of China and India in world development.

CHINA

·        Around the 10th century, the population of China counted about 60 millions, compared to about 40 millions in Western Europe, and a total world population of about 300 million. With an estimated size of an extended household of 10 members, it can be estimated that China had about 4 million households in the 10th century. About 95% of these households were rural and about 5% lived in urban areas.3 The rural farming population had the burden of feeding itself as well as the urban population. The latter consisted of imperial rulers, bureaucrats, military, craftsmen and other court supporters. At the same time, a significant shift in the concentration of households took place from North China where three-quarters of the population lived and where wheat and millet were the main crops around the 8th century, to the region below the Yangtze where rice cultivation dominated. This change permitted the population of China to double by the 13th century, release labour for handicraft production and raise general welfare to among the highest income per capita at the time.

 

·        First, how did the economy of millions of extended households with varying riches perceive and resolve the apparent conflict between kinship sharing and profit making?

The prevalent view is that while the Chinese family traditions favour kinship sharing, they oppose the full pooling of resources among family members. Hence, rivalry among brothers is encouraged, and rewards for leadership, performance and trust are applied. Proponents of this view point to past and present evidence on the emergence of prosperous family-based large-scale enterprises and new riches in China and by Chinese abroad, emphasizing that whenever the external circumstances were/are favourable, such opportunities were/are seized by the more fortunate households; and their successes were/are hailed and aspired by more households.

 

·         Second, how was the polity managed in the context of a vast country with millions of rural households and their catering economy?

Already from the 7th century, the Chinese dynasty was recruiting professionally trained public servants on a meritocracy basis, admission was subjected to examinations and advancement required evaluation. They serviced the central, provincial and district administrations. At the level of the district, the magistrate was tax collector, judge, record keeper and the local administrator, with a command on recruited clerks, policemen, guards and alike. The bureaucracy was a privileged class; their families enjoyed esteem and were exempt from many levies. Candidate bureaucrats, who qualified academically but failed to become officials, formed a supportive buffer stock, and enjoyed similar privileges but at a lower level. To discourage corruption, bureaucrats were regularly rotated.

 

·         The bureaucracy functioned in a primarily feudal agricultural economy. The bureaucracy invested enthusiastically and effectively in agriculture and got its due share in a growing agricultural income. They introduced hydraulic works and new crops, spread best techniques and innovations, resettled farmers in more fertile areas and developed stockpiling to mitigate famines. The concentration of the bureaucracy and gentry of Imperial China on agriculture had the consequence of ignoring industry. The urban workforce employed in industry, trade, transport, etc., basically representing firm settings, was deferential to the bureaucracy and depended on their good will. These firm settings did not enjoy legal protection. Bureaucratic decisions could not be challenged. Furthermore, the reserved attitude towards foreign elements and towards trading with the rest of the world (ROW) did not encourage the opening up of foreign markets and related commercial activities. The above biases failed to launch the country in the industrial age. The Chinese economy lagged further due to internal rebellions and external interventions involving wars with Japan, France and the United Kingdom.

 

·         The modernization of China started with the communist take-over in 1949. Being a federation of regions, each with vast territories and populations, decentralized decision making dominated. While the economic system was subordinated to political motives under the Maoist regime (1949 to 1978), economic considerations played increasingly a greater role thereafter, in the Deng and Zemin regimes. A series of economic reforms and a gradual introduction of private ownership pushed the economy to new heights, outperforming other major economies in the world. Crucial factors behind the outstanding economic performance of the Chinese economic system in the past three decades are usually categorized into three groups: the socio-cultural-political environment in which China was historically embedded, systemic features and government policies.

 

The socio-cultural and political environment in China relates to strong family loyalties, strength of ancient roots of entrepreneurship and a vast base of traditional and technological knowledge, the attitude to conserve owns culture, the relatively small size of ethnic minorities which fostered a homogeneous cultural outlook, and the high population pressure on farmland which imposed moderation in consumption and efficient resource use. The favourable systemic features refer to the traditional bureaucratic proficiency in administrating matters of interest to the state. The communist regime relied on the geographically decentralized, competitively oriented and rigorously selected party and non-party bureaucrats, in bolstering cooperation with the provincial rural population to achieve the most for the province, and control population growth, albeit distributing the outcome among the bureaucracy and the rural population under tacitly presumed sharing arrangements. The ruling regime has encouraged and has been guided by this selective approach in drawing up systemic changes for the future. Finally, the policies pursued by the ruling regime from 1978 onwards were economically sound. As was reviewed above, the agricultural mobilization was swiftly followed by the industrial restructuring and by an outward orientation of foreign trade and financial relations, within restrained tasks for the public sector.

 

·         The economic development of China can be broken down in four phases, which were also characteristic of the economic success stories of Japan and Korea, a few decades earlier. These are

(1) an agricultural shake-up that allows freeing of resources for industry;

(2) balanced physical, human and institutional infrastructures that allow industrial structuring and industrial breakthroughs;

(3) outward orientation of foreign trade and financial relations in harmony with circumstantial comparative advantages and

(4) restrained and effective tasks for the public sector.

 

·         China went through an agrarian reform that confiscated about half of the cultivated land, belonging to landlords, and redistributed this land to tenants and landless farmers. From the mid-1950s, agriculture was collectivized in the form of cooperatives with an average size of 200 families. In their free time, farmers can cultivate their own private tiny plots and sell them in limited free markets. These private plots did not count more than 5% of the total arable land. The Great Leap Forward between 1958 and 1962 enlarged the cooperatives to 5,000 families was associated with food shortages and distribution of food on basis of work points. Between 1962 and 1979 cooperatives reversed back to the other extreme of 20 to 30 families with about 7% in private plots.

 

Modern reforms started from 1979 with (a) extension of the limited free markets to household products such as poultry, livestock and related; (b) introduction of the responsibility system, which tied more closely received rewards to the targeted work performed. In a few years, the system developed into that of (c) collective units of individual households with cultivation rights for periods of about 15 years and (d) binding contracts on the collective units to deliver certain portions of the crops to the state/province at crop prices that were fixed by the state. As private incentives, (e) the state paid premiums for extra deliveries above the contract, and prices for attractive crops were raised. As transitional strategies, (f) the state introduced a dual system with a tendency for the official price to move towards widely known market prices.

 

The reforms resulted in a rocketing of the growth rate of agricultural output from 4.3% pa during 1971–1975 to 7.5% pa during 1980–1982 to 13.0% pa during 1982–1986. This significant growth in agriculture is fundamental for the industrial push that occurred.

 

·         Following the Soviet example, industrial enterprises became state enterprises in 1950, their objective was to maximize output subject to given input constraints as planned by the central or regional governments. The Great Leap Forward (1958–1960) introduced more centralization and dogma, resulted in economic failures and was followed by a substantive decentralization in decision making towards provincial and county levels. Most enterprises obtained inputs from own province and sold output in own province. Trade between provinces was in the hand of state trading firms in the provinces. Production in strategic sectors remained in Beijing.

 

The industrial reform, from around 1980 and onwards, consisted of four components:

(a) Creating product markets for inputs and outputs.

 (b) Making enterprise managers behave in accordance with market rules via the pursuit of profits, bankruptcy laws, government pre-determined rates of interest, creating boards of directors independent from bureaucracy.

(c) Introduction of competition and abolition of monopoly power especially manifested in loosening the inter-trade between provinces that was until then run solely by state trading firms, and in liberalizing the organization and provision of services.

(d) Setting prices in accordance with relative scarcities.

 

Differentiated stimulation and reform policies in industry were applied towards state-owned and state-participating enterprises, SOE, and various types of non-state owned enterprises, non-SOE, which discouraged SOE but favoured non-SOE. On the eve of economic reforms in 1978, SOE’s share in industrial output and employment amounted to 79% and 52%, respectively; some three and a half decades later in 2003, these shares fell to 37% and 14%.

 

The categories of SEO and non-SEO in China cover a complex differentiation of enterprises by status of ownership and registration. Within state ownership, the share of purely state-owned enterprises diminished, that of state participating enterprises, where the state controls a minority share, has increased significantly. While the bulk of state ownership has been shifted to the infrastructural sectors of energy, mining, electricity, water, communication, iron, chemicals and tobacco, the state participating enterprises are active in the consumer and intermediate goods industrial activities, including production for domestic and foreign markets. The state-owned enterprises are highly decentralized and are affiliated to one of three levels of government: central, provincial and county, with most of them under direction of the provincial and county governments. The Chinese economy is known to have multi-layer and multi-regional features. Furthermore, the traditional small size of state enterprises in terms of the average employment per enterprise has been maintained, compared to larger sizes of public enterprises in Russia and other former transition countries in the pre-transition period.

 

China’s capital market started from 1995, but its coverage is not inclusive, and its functioning suffers from its short-lived learning experience (uncertainties and speculations due to ambiguities in regulations, loose supervision, non-transparency, limited information access and use).

 

As regards the non-SOE sector, two important developments can be highlighted. First, in the first decade of the industrial reforms, roughly between 1980 and 1990, the emergence and growth of the collectives and cooperatives, especially township and village enterprises, known as TVEs, was crucial for shaping the domestically oriented industrial structure. In TVE, the means of production are owned collectively by the owners/workers, local government and more funds can be raised from the public. TVEs are generally characterized by ambiguous property rights, in the sense that rights of owners are not guaranteed beforehand. Instead, owners/workers have to fight for actual remuneration, ex-post. Second, in the second decade of the industrial reform and later, roughly from 1990 onwards, the driving force of industrial development shifted from the domestically oriented collectives and cooperatives to the outward-oriented commercial companies such as limited liability companies, shareholding corporations and foreign funded multinationals. Entrepreneurship in these companies focused increasingly on innovations, cost reduction, linking with exports and foreign direct investment (FDI) and increasing their share of both the domestic market that hence commands a huge purchasing power, and the foreign markets. In similarity with industrial restructuring, the ownership structure in construction and services shifted significantly from state and collective to private and other modes. While in 1978, state and collective ownership accounted for 90% of these two sectors, by 1996, the situation reversed with private and other types of ownership accounting for 93%.

 

·         The Stalin–Mao agreements of 1950 made China heavily dependent on the Soviet Union for purchase of foreign capital equipment and technical skills, and Chinese foreign trade went also in the direction of the Soviet Union. Soviet–Chinese geo-political relations deteriorated in the late 1950s, leading to a withdrawal of Soviet technicians and capital, and uncompleted investment projects. The economic isolation of China from the ROW (Rest of the World)  was reinforced furthermore by the Western boycott of China following its military manoeuvres in North Korea from 1950. As a result, foreign trade of China, which had a very limited scope in 1950, dropped further by a fifth during 1960–1970. As the Western economic boycott of China was relieved gradually, ending formally in 1971, and as the new political leadership in China saw the benefits of an open economy as was demonstrated by Japan, Taiwan, Korea, Singapore and Hong Kong, the Chinese government started from mid-1970s on relaxing foreign trade control, decentralizing foreign trade decisions and pricing, devaluating the yuan, setting up free trade zones with duty-free inputs and exports, and putting to use in the areas of production, trade and investment the very close relationship between Hong Kong and China.

 

The foreign trade policy of China with the rest of the world, ROW, focused on accelerated exports as the source of foreign exchange income, the predominance of manufactured goods in these exports, and the increased alignment of these manufactured exports with FDI and joint ventures.17 The negative foreign trade balance of 1980 shifted into positive from 1990 onwards, and reached staggering levels as the growth of merchandise exports became more closely attached to foreign funded enterprises and joint ventures empowered by large inflows of FDI. The early reliance of the country on international borrowing to finance investment in infrastructures came to a stop in years adjacent to 1995. At the same time, portfolio investment and FDI increased dramatically, and together with a mounting positive trade balance, China was able to form by 2003 the largest foreign exchange reserve held by a single country, at US$403,251 million, next to a substantive gold reserve. The accumulated foreign exchange reserves allowed China to become a capital importing to a capital exporting economy with due emphasis on development and possession and safeguarding future supply of natural resources for China from other development regions abroad.

 

The outward orientation of the Chinese economy is also gradually felt in its capital market. Trade is conducted in A shares and B shares. A shares are local shares and can only be bought by local (Chinese domestic) investors. B shares are only available to foreign investors. Only recently, Chinese are allowed to buy B shares, conditioned on the fact these purchases are done with foreign held capital. Foreign investors can buy A shares when they have official Qualified Foreign Institutional Investor (QFII) status. The stock exchanges of Shenzhen and Shanghai had capitalization values end 2012 of $2.31 trillion and $1.16 trillion, respectively; with these values, they count as the 6th and 15th largest stock exchanges in the world.

 

·         China has been able to restrain the tasks of the public sector and limit the shares of public revenue and public expenditure in the GDP. Furthermore, public revenue has become about equally divided between central and local governments, while public expenditure has shifted from the central to local levels. China makes use of extra public budgetary revenues and expenditures but the shares of these in the GDP have been falling down, and they are primarily meant to supplement the local fiscal balances. The budgetary deficit has been kept within the internationally respectable limits of 2.5% of the GDP.

 

 

INDIA

·        The origin of the Indian culture and territories is postulated by historians to be a merger between an Indus Valley civilization and invading Aryan tribes from the northwest. The modern history is dated from the 8th century, with the Arab invasion of India, followed in the 12th century by the Turks. Unification of the country occurred in the 17th century under the Moghul rule. While the involvement of European traders dated from the 15th century, British rule assumed political control by the 19th century. The Indian society, for several centuries before, under the Moghul rule, and under the British rule has greatly kept its characteristic feudally organized traditional village society. While as elsewhere, the feudal system divided the population into patronizing landlord households who owned land, and peasant households who cultivated the land and shared the produce with landlords, for the obtained patronage, typical for India was the village culture and the castes society.

 

Extended households related to each other by kinship populated the thousands of villages. All generations of the family lived together, pooled their income and consumed collectively. Because of the intra household intensive relationships, inward orientation of the villages, poor transport and contact between villages, the villages were largely self-sufficient. The feudal regime was backed by a castes society, which divided the population into rigid hereditary groups with clearly defined societal functions and ranked downwards from priests and landlords to warriors, traders, peasants and outcastes. By prohibiting inter group agent flows and emphasizing rank, the caste society discouraged self-esteem, social mobility and the development of strong nationalistic aspirations among the less privileged.

 

The first major foreign invader — the Moghuls — dominated India from about 1500 to around 1700, established control on Northern India that was mainly Muslim and Southern India that was all Hindu. The Moghul regime introduced the royal court and a bureaucratic aristocracy that was considerably foreign based. Moghul official consisted of controllers, accountants and judges installed at the level of collections of villages called jagir. They earned their incomes from revenues made by jagirs. The Moghul central government levied a land tax that was collected by controllers of jagirs, equivalent to about one-third of the crop production. The tax was used to support occupying troops and construction works. The Indian economy flourished during the Moghul rule, but political control on the various regions of India disintegrated by 1700 due to ethnic intolerance by Moghul rulers. The collapse of the Moghul empire led to a break-up of India in independent mostly run by warlords.

 

British rulers filled the political vacuum gradually, by conquering Bengal in 1757, and extending control to Madras and Bombay in 1803, and Punjab and Sindh in 1849. The British controlled India via a compact army of British soldiers and Indian mercenaries and an efficient bureaucracy that had a watchdog character. The zamindari played a crucial role as the watchdog. These were a group of landlord’s intermediary between government and land operating peasants; the British created them in 1793 from the tax-gatherers in Mughul India with the purpose of using them for the collection of land taxes and for the exercise of political control in rural areas.

 

Although village life and feudal features were paramount, some urban cities and towns in India under the Moghul rule experienced relatively high levels of industrious activities and economic welfare. The Indian cottage and textile industries were highly renowned at the time, and might have come close to a firm intensive setting, but they suffered significantly in terms of expansion under British rule. The region was also a magnet for regional trade in the 18th century, but again did not grow and lost much of its attraction in relation to other world regions in the 19th century and up to independence in the mid-20th century.

 

Non-violent resistance to British colonialism under M. Gandhi and J. Nehru led to independence in 1947. Gandhi idealized and urged for a communal and a traditional village life as the most humane way of life, but this fell out of step with the modernization paradigm of Nehru.26 Through a combination of factors like land reform, commercialization and the green revolution, traditional agricultural structure in India went through major changes. In the early years of independence, the central objective of land reform measures was the abolition of Zamindari. Fuelled by mainly nationalistic motivations, the abolition of semi-feudal intermediaries and the absentee landlords, who were allies of the British in British India, was successful.

 

From the hitherto absentee landlords emerged a small group that was ripe for transformation into capitalistic farmers, Kulaks. 27 Legislation on tenancy abolition encouraged these landlords to become rich and direct cultivators of their land, named Legislation towards elimination of feudal tenancy had also the effects of increasing the more purely commercial tenancy where labour works for a wage and raising the amount of land rented by kulaks. As a result, the kulaks were well on the way to becoming the new masters of the countryside. Greater demand for agricultural products and cultivated land, and the green revolution increased the wealth of the already prosperous and powerful kulaks.

 

·         The economic development of India was hardly any world news in the 1950s– 1990s. India’s potential became recognized a few years later than China’s potential. India had its own version of tackling the four prerequisites of systemic change necessary for a sustained take-off. These are, it is remembered:

(1) an agricultural shake-up that allows freeing of resources for industrialization;

 (2) balanced physical, human and institutional infrastructures that allow industrial structuring and industrial breakthroughs;

(3) outward orientation of foreign trade and financial relations in harmony with circumstantial comparative advantages and

(4) restrained tasks for the public sector

 

·         The green revolution, whose effects came later in time, is generally seen to be more crucial than land reform in transforming agriculture and supporting industry. While the Indian government fulfilled a role in transferring resources from agriculture to industry via its fiscal and double pricing systems, other factors played crucial roles in the transfers of labour and capital. The demographic pressure, failure of land reform, success of the green revolution and commercialization of agricultural land, all led to higher land prices compared to farm wages and compelled the out-migration of landless peasants to urban areas, and cheap labour was essential for starting industry.

 

·         In their effort to bolster national industrialization, Indian governments followed centralized policy making and implementation. This took the forms of nationalized infrastructural sectors such as public utilities, transport, communications; permission of state-owned firms to participate in and control iron and steel, cement, chemicals, electronics and other major manufacturing industries; regulated markets and policies that reserve certain activities of small-scale production to the unregistered and registered small establishments and exclude large-scale production; and imposition of protective import substitution measures, high tariffs and non-tariff barriers and foreign capital controls.

 

Furthermore, in the 1970s, India nationalized banking, mining, textile mills, wholesale grain and jute trade in rescue operations of failing private enterprises and threatened unemployment. During this and adjacent periods, the share of public investment in total investment increased, and that of private investment fell down. Private investment was subjected to a hoard of licences and regulations resulting in cooling the investment climate. These shifts from the private to the public sectors in India contrast remarkably with opposite shifts occurring in China and other East Asian countries.

 

In spite of the marginally greater resources put in the public sector, and despite the strong regulatory regime of the private sector, the annual growth rate of public sector GDP declined from 7.8% in the period 1960– 1975 to 7.2% in the period 1975–1990; while that of the private sector rose from 2.6 to 3.7%. Industrial restructuring suffered from an inadequate physical infrastructure in transport, communication and energy. The human infrastructure that was built and supported by the state was more oriented to higher than middle and vocational education and not conducive to industrial development. The financial infrastructure necessary for modern industry was absent. Recognition of the above gaps, together with gained knowledge on the positive effects of favourable investment climates and export promotion regimes for a few East Asian economies contributed to a reversal of state policies in India. By late 1970s, economists on trade and development were able to show that import substitution measures were often overextended and obstructed export promotion and the flow of FDI, both of which are important ingredients of economic development.

 

The newly elected Indian government in 1980, under Indira Gandhi, and later Rajiv Gandhi, made important openings to leading industrial firms and implemented targeted industrial measures towards major firms ranging from granting import licences to tax holidays, location wavers and credit guarantees. The measures created a positive investment climate and have been named as pro-business reforms in contrast to the pro-liberalization reforms that was launched in 1990 by the next government and that introduced liberalization domestic and foreign trade markets and export promotional reforms across the board, and started implementing a modest privatization programme of state enterprises. Indian growth was triggered by an attitudinal shift on the part of the national government towards a pro-business approach from 1980, as opposed to a pro-liberalization approach that started in 1990. Reliance in the 1980s was on existing business interests while in the 1990s, the emphasis was on restructuring and new entrants via liberalization. Of course, it is most likely that the performance of the 1980s would have run out of steam if the true liberalization reforms of 1990s were not implemented.

 

The combination of targeted and neutral outward-oriented economic reforms, and their phasing in that order, is not unique to India. It was done before by Japan and Korea, and has been followed by many developing countries. What is unique in the economic development of India is that the effects of the outward-oriented economic reforms, given internal structures and external circumstances, culminated in a higher economic growth in services than in industry, and set into motion a comparative advantage in modern services over industrial merchandise.

 

·         The higher comparative advantage of India in modern services over industrial merchandise has come as a surprise to many. Exports of modern services include software development, and information communication technologies (ICT)-enabled services ranging from back office operations, revenue accounting, data entry and conversion, database development; to the processing of medical transcriptions, insurance claims, educational content and publications; remote maintenance and support; and call centres.

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND ECONOMIC ORIENTATION

·        China’s growth of the GDP for the period of 1993–2004 is accounted for by almost equivalent contributions of the growth of capital inputs and growth of factor productivity at about 44 and 42%, respectively; and their contributions have been increasing compared to the previous period of 1978–1993. The contributions of growth in labour quantity and labour quality (i.e. labour education) inputs to economic growth are relatively low at 12% and 2%; and these are down compared to the previous period. Growth accounting for India for the periods 1960–1980 and 1980–2004 shows the contribution of capital growth to economic growth to be stable at about 24%, a diminishing contribution of labour quantity growth at 33.3%, and increasing contributions of labour education growth, with factor productivity growth reaching 7% and 35%, respectively. The comparisons show that growth in capital and factor productivity play greater roles in economic growth in China than in India, though the lag is being closed with factor productivity. In contrast, labour education and labour quantity are more significant as contributing factors to economic growth in India than in China, but here too, the contribution of labour quantity is diminishing as was observed for China, earlier.

 

In China, during 1993–2004, the contributions of the primary, secondary and tertiary sectors — more or less agriculture, industry and services — amounted to 8, 59 and 29%, respectively. Industry is thus the highest. The remaining 21% is due to reallocations between the sectors, mainly from agriculture to industry and services. The reallocation accounts thus for about 2% annual economic growth of an aggregate growth of 9.6%. For India in the period 1993–2004, the contributions of agriculture, industry and services amounted to 11, 19 and 45%, respectively. The services sector is thus the highest contributor in India in contrast to China where industry is the highest contributor. The remaining 25% is due to reallocations between the sectors, mainly from agriculture to industry and services.  The relative contribution of the reallocation component is slightly higher in India than in China, suggesting that in that period the economic restructuring in India was higher than in China.

 

·        In an assessment of the displacement hypotheses, it is important to determine whether the economies of China and India are tending more towards becoming fierce competitors of each other or filling complimentary positions in a globalizing economy. If they are fierce competitors, then one of the two will probably be more successful than the other in the long run, and the group of world leading economies will be joined by one newcomer resulting in the displacement of one incumbent. On the other hand, when both the economies of China and India have tendencies to occupy complimentary positions in a globalizing world, and grow rapidly in more or less equivalent rates, both countries would at some time become leading newcomers resulting in the displacement of two incumbents. A complimentary relationship between the economies of China and India viewed in a global perspective is likely to widen the displacement effects for the leading incumbents.

 

The ensuing comparative advantage in foreign trade can be viewed from a demand side and a supply side. Take the demand side, countries at about the same level of income per head have similar demand patterns and would be competitors of each other in that respect. Countries with differing levels of economic welfare have different demand patterns, and thus minimizing inter-competition. This latter situation would apply more to China and India. Taking the supply side, decomposition analysis of GDP growth in industry and services shows China to surpass India with a higher factor productivity growth in industry, and in contrast, India is shown to surpass China with a higher productivity growth in services. As in China, so also in India the incoming FDI tended to be invested in lines that associate with the lines of exports. But there is a significant difference between the two countries. In China, the lines of FDI and exports are primarily concentrated in the production of merchandise goods with little in services. This is otherwise in India, where FDI is more focussed in services.

 

Even though the two countries occupy for now complementary positions, they still compete for foreign sources of trade and investment from the ROW. Under austere scarcity conditions, ROW cannot escape at one time making economic choices between the two giant economies. The then would-be-held expectations of the relative future prospects of the two economies could play a significant role in determining the future courses of the two economies. In the meantime, however, the domestic component of these economies is becoming larger and can be become the self-propelling growth mechanism, with less dependence on the foreign sector and ROW flows.

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND INCOME INEQUALITY

·        As usual, the forecasts and analysis on the displacement hypothesis are conditional on the absence of major external and internal constraints. At the external front, assumed is the absence of economic calamities caused by world recessions, credit crunch, trade protectionism, inelastic supply of energy resources; and at the internal front assumed is absence of social and political instability caused by inequality divides, poverty hazards, ethnic conflicts, civil disorder, polity shake-up or financial mismanagement. Regarding internal risk constraints, the ultimate realization of the future economic prospects would require stable and sustainable societies and polities.

·        The evaluation of increases in income inequality cannot be done in isolation from the growth in income per capita, since both effects associate in the development context, and there is a trade-off between the two effects. We formulated and applied an inequality well-being trade-off defined as change in the Gini index between t and t − 1 divided by the growth rate of GDP per capita in t. Higher positive values of the elasticity are indicative of a greater tension between inequality and wellbeing, meaning that there is a larger increase in the Gini index with every one percentage growth in the GDP per capita.

·        growth–inequality disruption crisis: critical test of balancing growth with inequality

CONCLUDING REMARKS

·         We described the bigger and highly dualistic countries of China and India as multi-poles and emphasized the important role of persuasion settings in the coordination of their social system. Although China does not have an active parliament that can contribute to persuasive outcomes, the country has developed other forms of persuasion settings. The Congress of the Communist Party, held every five years, is a major persuasion setting that outlines future actions to be taken in terms of institutions and policies, and appoints the right authorities to lead, defend and implement the actions. Other very popular persuasion settings in China are councils of knowledgeable experts that attempt to reach consensus solutions to outstanding problems.


 Chapter 8  SYSTEM COMPETITION AND WORLD GOVERNANCE IN THE NEAR FUTURE

LEADING REGIONS AT THE WORLD LEVEL

·        The larger the number of agents and the larger the size of the economic transformation in one subsystem, the greater the influence will be of that subsystem in its interactions with other subsystems. We formulated a DI based on the relative shares of agents and gross domestic product (GDP) to represent the degree of influence of subsystems in the whole system. Once the dominance of one specific subsystem overpasses the signals of an over majority (say >80%), this specific subsystem tends to overrun the whole system. We can look at the economy of the whole world as one world economic system, and the economies of the eight regions as subsystems in the world economic systems. The relative shares of the regional subsystems in the total world population and in the total world GDP are the arguments that determine the DI of the regional subsystems.



 

LEADING COUNTRIES AT THE REGIONAL LEVEL

·        The higher the index of a leading country x the greater is x’s influence in passing the behavioural features of x to follower countries. The leading country is likely to become the one and only one dominant player in the region once a threshold value of DI is passed; which related literature suggests to be around 80%. Once this threshold is passed, there is a surge in the likelihood that the behavioural features of the dominant player spread vigorously and ending up as the standard mode in follower countries.



 

· 

LEADING COUNTRIES AT THE WORLD LEVEL

·        Leading countries played prominent roles in past world development. Italy as the playground for the Papal Revolution, and in resemblance the German, English, American, French and Russian revolutions, Spain and Portugal leading the age of discoveries, Britain leading the industrial revolution and US leading firm intensive anchoring in economic systems, etc., China and India, as upcoming global leaders, can be expected to bring new ideas and new ways of conducting things that can be adapted, spread worldwide and impacting as to become aspects of world development, with lasting impacts on economic systems.




We presented earlier in Table the DI of leading regions, r, at the world level, w; the operation can be expressed as (r/w); and we presented  the DI for leading countries, c, at the regional level, r; this operation can be expressed by (c/r).  This section deals with leading countries at the world level, or (c/w). Calculation of the DI for (c/w) is straightforward. It is obtained by multiplying DI results for (r/w), by DI results for (c/r ) giving the value of DI for each country at the world level

LEADING COUNTRIES IN THE NEAR FUTURE

To compute the DI for leading countries in future years, one needs projections of the population shares and the GDP shares of leading countries in the world’s total population and GDP, respectively. United Nations Demographic Division is the primary source for population projections. Reference was already made to PWC (2011) as our source of projections for the GDP. These two types of projections are employed to compute DI for leading countries for 2030 and 2050.



EXPLORING DESIGNS FOR WORLD GOVERNANCE

·        The current world governance system was shaped in the advent of WWII, and has undergone a few additional changes since then. The United Nations assembly consists of 193 member states. The UN security council consists of five permanent members with veto rights: China, France, Russian Federation, the United Kingdom and the United States, and 10 nonpermanent members elected for two-year terms by the General Assembly. There are permanent international agencies on trade, finance, law and all areas of major social and economic activities, and intermittent conferences on newly rising global challenges. The latest development in world governance is the establishment of the G-20, which is a forum of political leaders of the 20 leading economies in the world.

·        Responsive actions to global failure require a world governance that is fairly representative of regional and country interests. A world polity that circles around individual countries with the highest GDP is ineffective in a world of 193 countries with 173 of them not participating. We worked our way in this book by focusing on eight world regions that were shown to be internally converging. It is instructive to demonstrate how the composition of a world top of presidential leaders (to be entrusted with coordinating world governance and resolving global failure) along our lines of thought would look like. Our list will be very different from the above-mentioned G-20 for several reasons.

 

First, we employ influence potential based on population and GDP, which is more democratic and more real. Second, our starting point will be regional representation, followed by naming countries, which is more democratic and more logic. Third, subject to explicitly set minimum and maximum rules, our outcome regarding representation is straightforward. This is not the case with G-20, which includes countries that do not qualify for the GDP criteria, and excludes others which do qualify, pointing thus to manipulated selections. Fourth, a forum of 20 top leaders is too big to be effective. Our list is restrained to 14 members

 

By eliminations, it ends up in a list of W-14. The list consists of US, Japan, Germany, France (for FIS), Russia (for RRTC), China, Indonesia (for EAP), India (for SA), Turkey (for CAC), Saudi Arabia (for MENA), Nigeria, South Africa (for SSA) and Brazil, Mexico (for LAC). It is noted that this list of 14 leading countries account for about two thirds of the full scale of the world DI, with the rest of the countries, about 180 controlling one-third of the world DI.

 

There is a rationale for supplementing the W-14 by a chamber of regional ambassadors who can represent the interests of the countries in the region other than that of the leading country. We refer here to the EU in the FIS group, the ASEAN in EAP, SARC in SA, the Arab League in MENA, etc. A chamber of eight regional ambassadors (say, the presidents of the above-mentioned organizations) can be installed to that effect, call it R-8, and it can convene on a regular basis in much the same way as W-14, and cooperate together in fixing world governance and global failures. Such an arrangement is already accommodated in the G-20 with respect to the EU; and it proves essential for streamlining policies at the country, regional and world levels.

 

 

THANK YOU !




 


 

 




Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Notes Taken From Landreth's and Colander's Book "History of Economic Thought"

 Notes Taken From Landreth's and Colander's Book  "History of Economic Thought" Chapter 1: Introduction   ·          Economic thought consists of both a vision and a formal theory. The vision is the broad perception with which individuals look at the world. The theory comprises the specific models that capture the vision. To understand the thought of individual economists, one must understand both their vision and their model.   ·          Economics is a social science. It examines the problems that societies face because individuals desire to consume more goods and services than are available, creating a condition of relative scarcity. To meet the problem of scarcity, a social mechanism is required for allocating limited resources among unlimited alternatives. Historically, four mechanisms have been used to deal with the problem of scarcity: Brute force, Tradition, Authority and Market. Resource allocation mechanisms determine who gets, and who does not

Notes taken from Ha Joon Chang's book "Economics: The User's Guide"

  Notes taken from Ha-Joon Chang's book " Economics: The User's Guide " Chapter 1 What is Economics ·          In the run-up to the 2008 financial crisis, the majority of the economics profession was preaching to the world that markets are rarely wrong and that modern economics has found ways to iron out those few wrinkles that markets may have; Robert Lucas, the 1995 winner of the Nobel Prize in Economics,* had declared in 2003 that the ‘problem of depression prevention has been solved’. 1 So most economists were caught completely by surprise by the 2008 global financial crisis.† Not only that, they have not been able to come up with decent solutions to the ongoing aftermaths of that crisis.   ·          Physical money – be it a banknote, a gold coin or the huge, virtually immovable stones that were used as money in some Pacific islands – is only a symbol. Money is a symbol of what others in your society owe you, or your claim on particular amounts of the socie

Notes taken from Bottomore's book "The Socialist Economy: Theory and practice"

Notes taken from Tom Bottomore's Book  "The Socialist Economy: Theory and practice"   Introduction: Socialist economy and socialist society ·         Socialism, as a political doctrine and a social movement, has never set itself purely economic aims. From the beginning its ideal was the creation of a new type of society, or, as Gramsci expressed it, 'a new civilization'. Some critics indeed have argued that socialist thinkers, at any rate until the 1920s, largely ignored the question of how a socialist economy would actually function; and Mises (1920, 1922), in one of the most extreme and vitriolic attacks, claimed to show that it would not function at all. ·         There are, to be sure, diverse conception of socialism , but what is common to almost all of them is a conviction of the fundamental importance of the economy in shaping social life as a whole: an idea which found its most trenchant expression in Marx’s social theory. I shall interpret that theory , w